• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Next (but not new) Frontier for Sovereign Default

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "The Next (but not new) Frontier for Sovereign Default"

Copied!
8
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

The Next (but not new) Frontier for Sovereign Default

Reinhart, Carmen

University of Maryland

April 2008

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/11865/

MPRA Paper No. 11865, posted 02 Dec 2008 06:48 UTC

(2)

May 12, 2008

The Next (but not new) Frontier for Sovereign Default 1

Carmen M. Reinhart University of Maryland and NBER

There is a view today that “this time it’s different” for emerging markets.

Governments are reducing their dependence on external debt and relying more on domestic debt financing for the first time! Furthermore, emerging market governments are increasingly issuing long-term domestic debt. Indeed, often this change in

government debt management patterns is taken as evidence of graduation from “serial default.” In this new world, debt crises in emerging markets will be a thing of the past, and the IMF is plainly out of business.2

Domestic debt is not a new invention

Yet, alas, apparently unknown to most observers in financial, academic, and policy circles, domestic debt has been around for a quite a while. For that matter, so too has been default on domestic debt of one form or another. In our latest paper, Kenneth Rogoff and I unearth a vast trove of historical time series data on external and domestic public debt for 64 countries ranging back to 1914. Our key sources are publications of the now-defunct League of Nations, updates by its successor, the United Nations, and the work of many scholars and government agencies.

1This article is based on Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff’s (2008) “The Forgotten History of Domestic Debt.” NBER Working Paper 13946, April (2008).

2 Carmen M. Reinhart, Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano (2003). “Debt Intolerance,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 1–74, document cases of “serial default,” that is cases where

governments have repeatedly defaulted or restructured their debts (including publicly-guaranteed debts);

Venezuela with 9 defaults since independence holds the record among today’s emerging markets.

(3)

Although it may come as quite a surprise to most readers that historical time series on domestic debt should be exotic for so many countries, it is. This is in contrast to external sovereign debt, on which there is a vast literature. We are not aware of any

academic or policy study that uses similar data, certainly not one encompassing such a long time period and so many countries.

Indeed, historical data on domestic (internal) government debt has been ignored for so long that many observers have come to believe that the recent rise in domestic debt in many emerging markets is novel. This perspective is based on the belief that,

historically, domestic government debt played only a minor role in the public finances of most developing countries. The new data thoroughly dispels this notion. The key findings of Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) are summarized in the remainder of this article.

First, domestic debt is and was large—for the 64 countries for which we have long time series, domestic debt averages almost two-thirds of total public debt; the increase in the share of domestic debt in the last few years is but an upward “blip” in the larger context. For most of the sample, these debts typically carried a market interest rate, except for the era of financial repression after World War II. From 1914 through the 1960s, before inflation became a widespread phenomenon, more than one-half of domestic debt was long term, even for Latin America.

(4)

Figure 1

Domestic Public Debt as a Share of Total Debt, 1900-2006

0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00

1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Share

of which North America

All countries

of which Latin America

The puzzle of “debt intolerance”

Recognizing the significance of domestic debt goes a long way toward

explaining the puzzle of why many countries default on (or restructure) their external debts at seemingly low debt thresholds. In fact, when heretofore ignored domestic debt obligations are taken into account (as shown in Figure 2), fiscal duress at the time of default is often revealed to be considerably more severe.3 Specifically, debt-to-revenue ratios are about twice as high for total (domestic plus external) debt as the standard ratios that only considered external indebtedness.

3 This puzzling “debt intolerance” is examined by Reinhart, Rogoff, and Savastano (2003).

(5)

Default through inflation

Domestic debt may also explain the paradox of why some governments seem to choose inflation rates far above any level that might be rationalized by seignorage revenues levered off the monetary base. (This was the puzzle first pointed out in Cagan’s classic, 1956, article on post-war hyperinflations.)4 Although domestic debt is largely ignored in the vast empirical literature on high and hyper-inflation, we find that there are many cases where the hidden overhang of domestic public debt was at least the same order of magnitude as base money, and more often than not, a large multiple, as shown in Figure 3..

4Cagan, Philip (1956). “The Money Dynamics of Hyperinflation.” In Milton Friedman (ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Figure 2. Public Debt-to-Revenue Ratios During External Default: 89 Episodes, 1827-2003

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00

Africa Asia Europe Latin America

Ratio

Total Debt

External Debt

(6)

Figure 3

Domestic Debt and Monetary Base During High Inflation

0 50 100 150 200 250 300

Argentina, 1989

Brazil, 1990

Germany, 1920

Greece, 1923

Italy, 1920

Japan, 1945

Norway, 1920

Philippines, 1984

Turkey, 1994

As a Percent of GD

Domestic debt/GDP

Base money/GDP

Outright defaults on domestic debt

Where there are domestic debts there is also domestic default. Our paper offers a first attempt to catalogue episodes of outright defaults on and reschedulings of domestic public debt across more than a century. This phenomenon appears to be somewhat rarer than external default, but far too common to justify the extreme assumption that

governments always honor the nominal face value of domestic debt. When outright default on domestic debt does occur, it appears to occur under situations of greater duress than for pure external defaults—both in terms of an implosion of output and marked escalation of inflation. As shown in Figure 4, in the runup to a default on

(7)

external debt, the economy is stagnant or in recession (on average, real per capita GDP edges down slightly from its level four years before the crisis); on the eve of domestic default, however, the output contraction is much deeper, as GDP registers an average decline of about 8 percent.

It is important to note that we do not here catalogue episodes of major de facto partial defaults, say through a sharp unexpected increase in financial repression (e.g., of the type China still imposes today).

Figure 4

Domestic and ex ternal crises Level of real GDP, index t-4=100

90 92 94 96 98 100 102 104

Four years before Three years before Two years before One year before Year of crisis One year after Two years after Three years after

Domestic External

Reflections on future prospects

Celebration about graduating from a history of serial default may be premature. This author is skeptical that proposed remedies to the syndrome of serial default, such as

(8)

contingent debt contracts (for example, see those discussed by Guimaraes) will

significantly lessen the likelihood of sovereign default or restructuring. 5 One variety of a state-contingent contract is inflation-indexed debt. At the time of this writing, Argentina is engineering a partial default on its domestic debt by significantly understating the domestic inflation rate (reported at about 8 percent) to which the debt is indexed.

Unofficial estimates of inflation are in the order of 25 to 30 percent.6

Governments that have repeatedly defaulted on their external debts, inflated away or outright defaulted their domestic debts, will, in all likelihood, not hesitate to default again.

5 See Bernardo Guimaraes “Emerging economies’ debt contingent on world real interest rates,” VoxEU October 8, 2007.

6 For instance, see the story reported by the news agency Bloomberg on January 23, 2008. It led off,

“Argentina's real inflation rate in 2007 was almost three times the official figure as a result of data manipulation, the union representing the National Statistics Institute's workers said in a report.”

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

European Commission, 2011) union density ratios and bargaining coverage rates, two basic indicators for any description and evaluation of institutionalized employment relations,

Adopting various scenarios for the exogenous variables viz., US GDP growth, oil price change, long term interest rates, and Euro vs dollar exchange rate, we predict that the

Adopting various scenarios for the exogenous variables viz., US GDP growth, German GDP growth, oil price changes and short-term interest rates, we predict that France’s debt

Adopting various scenarios for the exogenous variables viz., US and French GDP growth, oil price changes and short-term interest rates, we predict that the debt-to-GDP ratio

By January 2009, the Global Economic Monitor, published by Institute for International Finance, detailed the packages either adopted or planned in about 20 advanced and

Foreign Debt and Domestic Savings In Developing Countries. Luke, Okafor and

Countries that managed to realize economic growth with a debt overhang would assume that the benefits of such growth would accrue to the creditors of public debt as the country

The conference Frameworks for Sovereign Debt Restructuring was held at Columbia University on November 17, 2014 with the sponsorship of the Initiative for Policy Dialogue (IPD),