• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Connecting time-use, travel and shopping behavior: Results of a multi-stage household survey

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Connecting time-use, travel and shopping behavior: Results of a multi-stage household survey"

Copied!
55
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Research Collection

Presentation

Connecting time-use, travel and shopping behavior Results of a multi-stage household survey

Author(s):

Schmid, Basil Publication Date:

2019-09-24 Permanent Link:

https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-b-000366670

Rights / License:

In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted

This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection. For more information please consult the Terms of use.

ETH Library

(2)

Connecting time-use, travel and shopping behavior: Results of a multi-stage household survey

Basil Schmid IVTETH Zurich

PhD Thesis Defence

Zurich, September 24, 2019

(3)

Introduction

Post-Car World (SNF project): Travel behavior in a (quasi-)car-less hypothetical environment (Schmid et al., 2019a)

=⇒ Pre-Post-Car World

• How do respondents trade-off different attributes in their (short- and long-term) choice and scheduling behavior?

• How are individual preferences for time-use, travel and shopping behavior related to each other?

• What is the role innovative mode sharing systems such as carsharing (CS) and carpooling (CP)?

– Valuation of level-of-service attributes

(4)

Fieldwork and response behavior

• Canton of Zurich (2015/16)

• 7’500 households invited by mail

• 50 CHF incentive payment

≈ 5% net cooperation rate

≈ 55% response rate (after recruitment)

• Final dataset:

≈ 300 households (red dots)

≈ 450 respondents

(5)

Survey methods: Three-stage household survey

• Revealed preference (RP; stage I) data: One-week reporting period on ...

– Travel behavior and time-use

– ICT usage (shopping, entertainment, etc.) – Daily and long-term expenditures

• Stated preference (SP; stage II) data on ...

– Mode choice – Route choice

– Shopping channel choice

• Stated adaptation (SA; stage III) data on ...

– Daily scheduling – Mobility tool ownership

(6)

The value of (travel) time: VTTS, VoL and VTAT

• Decomposition of the value of travel time savings (VTTS) into two components (DeSerpa, 1971; Jara-Diaz and Guevara, 2003)

VTTSi,n

| {z }

typically>0

=VoLn

| {z }

>0

VTATi,n

| {z }

<or>0

– VTTS: Money value of indirect utility obtained from decrease in travel time – VoL: Money value to reduce travel time in favor of other activities;

opportunity value of time

– VTAT: Money value of the (dis)pleasure of travel time itself; depends on the conditions/comfort of travel

(7)

VTTS, VoL and VTAT: Policy relevance

• VTTS: Biggest share of user benefits in cost-benefit analyses

– Decisive role in the ranking of investment projects that affect travel time – Empirical basis for modeling and forecasting of travel behavior

=⇒ Identify mode and user-type effects in the VTTS

• VoL: Assessing the options under a budget constraint

VTTS [CHF/h] VoL [CHF/h] VTAT [CHF/h] Invest in ... Implication

20 5 –15 Conditions VTTS

20 20 0 Cond./speed VTTS/travel time

20 35 15 Speed Travel time

(8)

VoL and VTTS: Overview and main model variables

• VoL (H¨ossinger et al., 2019): Time assigned to activities (incl. work) and expenditures assigned to goods consumption, wage rate and fixed income (RP)

• VTTS (Schmid et al., 2019b): Travel choices (RP/SP) among a set of available alternatives with corresponding attributes (travel cost, travel time, etc.)

Mode Individual (user) Trip Random

VTTS VTTS/VoL VTTS VTTS/VoL

MIV Sex Distance Error components (VTTS)

PT Age Trip purpose Scale (VTTS)

CS Kids in HH Daily weather Taste (VTTS/VoL)

CP Couple Weekend vs. weekday

Bike Residential location area Walk Education

Personal income

(9)

SP route choice: Example choice situation

(10)

Mode-specific VTTS and VoL [CHF/h]

0102030405060VTTS and VoL [CHF/h]

Walk

Bike

MIV

PT

CS CP

VoL

(11)

VoL, VTTS and VTAT: Main findings

• VoL ≈52% of wage rate (49.5 CHF/h)

– Zurich has strong preference for goods consumption relative to leisure

• VTAT negative for car modes (MIV, CS and CP), positive for PT and bike – Conditions/quality of travel higher in PT and bike

– E.g. MIV vs. PT: Mode effect always dominates user-type effects

• VoL and VTTS are only weakly related

– Income has no effect on the VTTS, but on VoL

– Individual travel preferences (VTTS) mostly uncoupled with the opportunity value of time (VoL)

– Anomaly for Zurich? $$$$-income region with small share of mobility expenditures ...

(12)

In-store or online shopping?

• Goals, methods and main hypotheses (Schmid and Axhausen, 2019):

– Exploring key determinants for choice btw. in-store and online shopping

=⇒ Comparison of the value of delivery time (VDTS) and the VTTS – Search goods (standard electronic appliances): More easily evaluated from

externally provided information

– Experience goods (groceries): Preferably inspected physically – Incorporating attitudes in decision process

• Experimental framing:

– Home-based round trip for in-store alternative

– No private cars; no multi-channel shopping; no social motives – Goods quality is assumed to be identical

(13)

In-store or online shopping: Example choice situations

Ordering me / shopping me Travel me to store

Size / weight of the goods basket

Your choice

Situaon 1 Order Travel to store

CHF 5.20

600.00 54 39

48

540.00 min. 1 week

CHF

CHF

min. min.

min.

CHF Delivery me (incl.

possible delays)

Shopping cost Delivery cost / travel cost

Situaon 2

5.00 CHF

0.00 9.10

600.00 66 21

58

600.00 2-3 days

CHF

CHF

min. min.

min.

CHF Purpose: Electronic appl.

Ordering me / shopping me Travel me to store

Size / weight of the goods basket

Your choice

Order Travel to

store

Delivery me (incl.

possible delays)

Shopping cost Delivery cost / travel cost Purpose: Electronic appl.

13

(14)

In-store or online shopping? Main findings I

• VTTS vs. VDTS:

Median VTTS shopping trips (groceries) [CHF/h] 54.4 VTTS shopping trips (electronics) [CHF/h] 29.3 VDTS delivery time (groceries) [CHF/day] 9.8 VDTS delivery time (electronics) [CHF/day] 1.2

• Context-dependent cost sensitivity: Delivery vs. shopping vs. travel cost

– Develop effective retailing strategies (i.e. delivery as part of shopping cost)

• Pro-online shopping attitudes higher shopping cost sensitivity:

Larger choice set when considering both shopping channels

• Socioeconomic profile of online/in-store shoppers

– Forecasting: (1) direct effects and (2) mediated via attitudes ...

(15)

Adaptations in car usage and ownership

• Goals, methods and main hypotheses:

– Assessing radical pricing effects from an activity-based perspective

=⇒ 4 adaptation scenarios (daily scheduling and mobility tool ownership experiment) with increasing variable MIV costs

– Understand and quantify the transition towards a Post-Car World

=⇒ Comparison of the MIV cost elasticities between the two experiments (1%increasein cost → x %decrease in distance traveled)

– Substitution effects may eventually lead to a decreasing cost elasticity

• Experimental framing:

– Future policies to reduce MIV usage; promotion of of shared mobility – Road tolls, congestion and fuel taxes

(16)

Daily scheduling experiment: Example scenario

(17)

Mobility tool ownership experiment: Example scenario

(18)

Adaptations in car usage: Main findings

• Daily scheduling experiment: ≈ −0.4→ medium-run (upper-bound?)

• Mobility tool ownership experiment: ≈ −0.15 → long-run (lower-bound?)

=⇒ Reflects substitution patterns towards more energy-efficient cars

• Hypothesized pathway of cost elasticities:

(19)

Summary and conclusions

• Main contributions of the thesis:

– Unique survey design

– Connecting the value of leisure, travel and delivery time using sophisticated modeling approaches with clear suggestions for policy and practice

– Quantitative assessment of car usage from a mobility pricing perspective

• Main limitations:

– Sampling bias (participation choice and response behavior) – Data resolution (activities) and quality (expenditures)

– Hypothetical bias (no private cars, experimental framing, etc.)

(20)

Questions?

(21)

Literature

DeSerpa, A. C. (1971) A theory of the economics of time,The Economic Journal,81(342) 828–846.

ossinger, R., F. Aschauer, S. Jokubauskaite, B. Schmid, S. Peer, R. Gerike, S. R. Jara-Diaz and K. W. Axhausen (2019) A joint time assignment and expenditure allocation model: Value of leisure and value of time assigned to travel for specific population segments,Transportation(in press).

Jara-Diaz, S. R. and C. A. Guevara (2003) Behind the subjective value of travel time savings: The perception of work, leisure and travel,Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,37(1) 29–46.

Jara-Diaz, S. R., M. A. Munizaga, P. Greeven, R. Guerra and K. W. Axhausen (2008) Estimating the value of leisure from a time allocation model, Transportation Research Part B: Methodological,42(10) 946–957.

Molloy, J., B. Schmid, F. Becker and K. W. Axhausen (2019) mixl: An open-source R package for estimating complex choice models on large datasets, Working Paper, 1408, Institute for Transport Planning and Systems (IVT), ETH Zurich, Zurich.

Petrin, A. and K. Train (2010) A control function approach to endogeneity in consumer choice models,Journal of Marketing Research,47(1) 3–13.

Schmid, B. and K. W. Axhausen (2019) In-store or online shopping of search and experience goods: A hybrid choice approach,Journal of Choice Modelling,31, 156–180.

Schmid, B., M. Balac and K. W. Axhausen (2019a) Post-Car World: Data collection methods and response behavior in a multi-stage travel survey, Transportation,46(2) 425–492.

Schmid, B., F. Aschauer, S. Jokubauskaite, S. Peer, R. H¨ossinger, R. Gerike, S. R. Jara-Diaz and K.W. Axhausen (2019b) A pooled RP/SP mode, route and destination choice model to investigate mode and user-type effects in the value of travel time savings,Transportation Research Part A:

Policy and Practice,124, 262–294.

(22)

Appendix: Response behavior, by survey wave

Pre-Test Wave 1 Wave 2 Wave 3 Stage I survey period: Jan. 2015 Jul. 2015 Oct. 2015 Apr. 2016

Number of households invited: 800 1600 3500 1600

Contacted by phone: 270 676 1110 546

Rejected participation: 203 543 919 428

Accepted participation: 67 133 191 118

Response burden scores of stage I: 3500 1700 1700 1700

Response rate stage I: 52.2% 54.8% 64.9% 66.9%

Response burden scores of stage II: 530 350 350 350

Response rate stage II: 52.2% 54.8% 61.7 % 63.6%

Response burden scores of stage III: 270 500 500

Estimated total response time 360 min. 215 min. 215 min. 170 min.

Final response rate: 52.2% 54.1% 60.2% 63.6%

Final cooperation rate: 4.9% 5.2% 3.8% 5.3%

(23)

Appendix: Response behavior for different incentive levels

• Sample selection participation choice Probit model – Incentive payments were varied in the pre-test

– 100 vs. 50 CHF: Increase in initial participation probability by 28%-points – Negative effect on completion conditional on participation of –33%-points

=⇒ net-effect on completion not statistically different from zero

Reject Participate Drop-out Complete Total

N [%] [%] [%] [%] [%]

Incentive 50 CHF 989 57.9 42.1 37.5 63.5 26.7

70/80 CHF 58 62.1 37.9 50.0 50.0 19.0

100 CHF 34 44.1 55.9 52.6 47.4 26.5

Sample N 1081 624 457 156 284 284

(24)

Appendix: Response burden and response rates @ IVT

020406080100Response Rate [%]

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000

Response Burden Score [−]

Prior recruitment and incentive Fit & 95 % CI Prior recruitment, no incentive Fit

No prior recruitment, no incentive Fit

PCW (Pre−Test) PCW (Wave I)

PCW (Wave II) PCW (Wave III)

a)

a) a)

a) a) a)

b) b)

c) c)

(25)

Appendix: Time-use model specification

• Log-linear additive function with diminishing marginal utility (Jara-Diaz et al., 2008; H¨ossinger et al., 2018)

Tw: Time assigned to work – Ti: Time assigned to activities

Ej: Expenditures assigned to goods consumption

θ andψ represent the baseline utility parameters max U = θwlog(Tw) +

I

X

i=1

θilog(Ti) +

J

X

j=1

ψjlog(Ej)

s.t. τTw

I

X

i=1

Ti = 0 (µ) TiTimin ≥0, ∀i ∈Ac (κi)

w ·Tw+Y

J

XEj ≥0 (λ) EjEjmin≥0, ∀j ∈Gcj)

(26)

Appendix: Mode/route choice as utility maximization

• Assume linear function of travel time and cost that one wants to minimize (mode-independent)

• Slopes are given by individual preferences → VTTSn

• Choice = mode/route with highest utility

(27)

Appendix: Conditional indirect utility function

• An individual behaves according to maxU(Xj,Qi)

s.t.X

j

PjXj +ciI

• Find optimal consumption Xj based on the discrete choicei with costci → conditional demand Xj(P,Ici,Qi) with available incomeIci

• Optimize overi → the conditional indirect utility function Vi is the maximum utility the individual would achieve if alternative i was chosen

Vi ≡U(Xj(P,Ici,Qi),Qi)

(28)

Appendix: Subjective value of a characteristic

• The marginal (unconditional) utility of income equals minus the marginal (conditional) dis-utility of costci

• The subjective value of an increasein quality characteristick in alternative i is defined as the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) between this characteristic and money (e.g. increase in cost ci) at constant utility

SVk,i = ∂Vi/∂Qk,i

∂V/∂I =−∂Vi/∂Qk,i

∂Vi/∂ci

• E.g. average willingness to pay for reductionin travel time VTTSi = βtt,i

βtc

(29)

Appendix: Time-use data

Category PCW [h] MAED [h] ATUS [h] Variable

Working 36.2 37.8 36.9 Tw

Wage rate [CHF/h] 49.5 14.5 w

Leisure 28.9 32.3 Tf1

Out-of-home leisure 16.4 Tf1

In-home leisure 9.6 Tf2

Eating 9.3 8.6 Tf2

Shopping 2.1 2.0 Tf2

Committed time 80.6 80.1 Tc

Travel 10.6 9.3 8.1 Tc

Shopping 1.9 Tc

Other 0.8 Tc

At home 92.5 Tc

Total (time constraint) 168.0 168.0 168.0 τ

(30)

Appendix: Expenditures data

Category PCW [%] MAED [%] HABE [%] Variable

Hotel, restaurants and holidays 11.4 6.2 7.5 Ef1

Leisure 2.9 7.8 3.9 Ef1

Clothes and accessories 5.3 5.6 3.1 Ef2

Electronics 2.2 3.6 2.0 Ef2

Taxes 23.1 10.8 Ec

Housing 18.6 23.2 18.7 Ec

Food 10.2 17.3 9.1 Ec

Health (incl. insurance) 7.0 2.4 9.8 Ec

Mobility 5.0 12.7 6.8 Ec

Communication 1.6 2.2 Ec

Furniture 1.6 2.4 1.3 Ec

Education 1.3 2.0 1.6 Ec

Services 1.8 3.1 2.0 Ec

Insurances1 3.0 8.2 17.6 Ec

Other expenditures 4.9 4.7 3.5 Ec

Avg. weekly expenditures [CHF] 1931.0 560.1 2309.7 PEf

j+Ec Avg. weekly labor income [CHF] 1995.6 550.7 2296.8 w·Tw

(31)

Appendix: VoL model estimation

• Four baseline utility parameters to be estimated: Λx,n∈ {θw, θTf1, ψEf1,Ψ} Λx,n=±exp(ζx +Znβx+ρx,n)

• The VoL for each individual is given by

VoLdn= ∂U/∂Ti

∂U/∂Ej = µ

λ = w·Tw+YEc Ψbn(τ−TwTc)

• Ψbn: Conditionals of the preference parameter for freely chosen goods relative time

µ andλ: Marginal utility of increasing available time/money (s.t. satiation)

• Decomposition of the VoL in a preference and data-driven component:

log(VoLdn) = −logΨbn

+ logw·Twd+YEc−logτTwdTc

(32)

Appendix: Discrete choice model specification

• Including time-use residuals to account for endogeneity (Petrin and Train, 2010)

• Mixed Logit model estimated in willingness-to-pay space (Schmid et al., 2019b)

VTTS^i,n,t = (VTTSi +Pn,tρVTTS,i+ZnκVTTS,i+ηVTTS,i,n)distn,t

dist

θVTTS,i

• The scale parameter is defined as

ψen,t = exp (βscale +Znκscale+ηscale,n)distn,t dist

θscale

>0 ∀ n,t

• The VTTS for each mode and individual is given by the conditionals VTTS\i,n

• Estimated in R 3.4.1 using mixl-package (Molloy et al., 2019)

(33)

Appendix: Travel choice data

• Discrete choice model: Pooled RP/SP panel data

• 12’594 choice observations, 362 individuals

02468Percent [%]

0 20 40 60 80 100

a) # choice observations per respondents

0510152025Percent [%]

Walk (MC_RP)Bike (MC_RP)MIV (MC_RP)PT (MC_RP)Walk (MC_SP)Bike (MC_SP)CP (MC_SP)CS (MC_SP)PT (MC_SP)

Alt. 1 (RC_CS)Alt. 2 (RC_CS)Alt. 3 (RC_CS)Alt. 1 (RC_PT)Alt. 2 (RC_PT)Alt. 3 (RC_PT)

b) Choice rates, by alternative (pooled data set)

(34)

Appendix: Time-use model estimation results

• All baseline utility main effects significant (p <0.01)

θw <0: Utility of working time negative

• Utility of out-of-home leisure significantly higher than in-home leisure

BASE INTER TUMIX

# estimated parameters 4 24 28

# respondents 362 362 362

# MLHS draws 2000

R2: Tw equation 0.73 0.73 0.77 R2: Tf1 equation 0.64 0.67 0.75 R2: Ef1equation 0.30 0.41 0.57

LLfinal 5592 5528 5510

AICc 11193 11109 11080

(35)

Appendix: VoL decomposition

log(money) log(time) log(exprate) log(pref.) log(VoL) Age [years] +0.34∗∗∗ −0.12∗∗ +0.39∗∗∗ +0.78∗∗∗ −0.19∗∗∗

Male +0.33∗∗∗ −0.09 +0.36∗∗∗ +0.49∗∗∗ +0.00

High educ. +0.27∗∗∗ −0.07 +0.29∗∗∗ +0.19∗∗∗ +0.16∗∗∗

Urban res. loc. +0.04 +0.05 +0.00 −0.00 +0.01

Couple +0.03 −0.09 +0.09 −0.02 +0.10

Kids −0.10 −0.12∗∗ +0.00 −0.55∗∗∗ +0.43∗∗∗

Inc. [CHF] +0.62∗∗∗ −0.10 +0.63∗∗∗ +0.38∗∗∗ +0.37∗∗∗

Money = available money component; time = available time component; exprate = expenditure rate;

pref. = preference component

Significance levels: ∗∗∗:p<0.01,∗∗:p<0.05,:p<0.1

(36)

Appendix: Choice model estimation results

• All mode-specific VTTS main effects significant (p<0.01)

• Endogeneity: LR test significant (8 df; increase in LL by 34.8 units)

• Trip explain much more than respondent characteristics

RMNL TMNL UMNL MIXL

# est. parameters 30 52 66 79

# respondents 356 356 356 356

# choice observations 12594 12594 12594 12594

# Sobol draws 5000

LLfinal 10875 8791 8617 6548

AICc 21816 17704 17397 13301

(37)

Appendix: Mode effects in VTTS

• MIV: Reference mode

• Residential location area: Strongest power in disentangling the total mode effect

MIV–PT MIV–CS MIV–CP

Total ∆VTTSi−j 15.8 –0.1 –2.1

Interquartile range (IQR) (19.0) (20.1) (17.3)

Ntotal 233 173 98

Female ∆VTTSi−j 21.2 10.9 2.2

Na 117 82 49

Male ∆VTTSi−j 8.7 –7.9 –5.7

Nb 116 91 49

Agglo./rural ∆VTTSi−j 19.3 5.1 1.2

Na 147 111 70

Urban ∆VTTSi−j 5.9 –6.5 –10.8

(38)

Appendix: VTTS and VoL correlation analysis

VTTS walk VTTS bike VTTS MIV

log(preference) −0.04 −0.11 −0.41∗∗∗

log(avail. money) −0.10 0.01 −0.21∗∗∗

log(avail. time) −0.18∗∗∗ 0.07 0.09

N 256 166 253

VTTS PT VTTS CS VTTS CP

log(preference) −0.23∗∗∗ −0.16∗∗ −0.36∗∗∗

log(avail. money) 0.00 0.05 −0.18∗∗

log(avail. time) 0.01 0.08 0.10

N 331 219 120

Significance levels: ∗∗∗:p<0.01,∗∗:p<0.05,:p<0.1

(39)

Appendix: Shopping attitudes

onl1: I often order products on the Internet onl2: Online shopping is associated with risks

onl3: Credit card fraud is one of the reasons why I don’t like online shopping onl4: The Internet has more cons than pros

onl5: Online shopping facilitates the comparison of prices and products

onl6: The risk of receiving a wrong product is one of the main reasons why I don’t like online shopping

onl7: I like to follow the new developments in the tech industry onl8: All I need, I find in the shops

onl9: Number of different IT gadgets in possession

ple1: I like to visit shops, even if I don’t want to buy something, just for looking around ple2: A disadvantage of online shopping is that I cannot physically examine the products ple3: Shopping usually is an annoying duty

(40)

Appendix: Correlation patterns and attitudes

PRO−ONLINE PLEASURE Male Age Income High education Car available HH members Store access.

Married Non−working Urban res. loc.

PLEASURE Male Age

Income Car available

Married Non−working

c > +0.3 +0.3 > c > +0.2 +0.1 > c > +0.2

−0.1 < c < −0.2

−0.2 < c < −0.3 c < −0.3

(41)

Appendix: Hybrid choice modeling framework

(42)

Appendix: HCM structural model I

The utility equations for shopping channeli ∈ {O,S}and individualn ∈ {1,2, ...,N}in choice scenariot ∈ {1,2, ...,Tn} with choice attributesXi,n,t and the latent variables LVz,nwith z ∈ {online shopping attitudes,pleasure of shopping} are given by

UO,n,t =XO,n,tβO +LVz,nµLVz +Zz,nΘz+f1,O,n,t+f3,n,t+ψO,n+O,n,t

US,n,t =XS,n,tβS+f1,S,n,t+f2,n,t+S,n,t where

f1,i,n,t = (βcost +Zonline,nonline,cost +ψcost,ncosti,n,t+ ϕLVonline,cost ·LVonline,n·costi,n,t

f2,n,t = (βtime,S +Zpleasure,npleasure,time,S+ψtime,S,ntimeS,n,t+ ϕLVpleasure,time·LVpleasure,n·timeS,n,t

f = (αM,L+α ·male +α ·agesizeM,L

(43)

Appendix: HCM structural model II and measurement model

The LV structural equations for latent variablez are linear functions of observed socioeconomic characteristicsZz,n for individualn:

LVz,n=Zz,nρz+ηLVz,n ηLVz,nN(0, σLV2 z)

The latent variable measurement equations with responses to the attitudinal questions (items)Iw,n with w ∈ {onl1,onl2, ...,ple3}are given by

Iw,n=Iw +τIwLVz,n+νw,n

νw,nN(0, σI2w)

(44)

Appendix: Calculation of valuation indicators

First obtain the conditional estimates of the shopping cost coefficientλ^cost,n, which is then used to calculate the weighted average marginal disutility of costCn for each individual:

λrcost,n=βbcost+Zonline,nbonline,cost +ψcost,nr +ϕbLVonline,costLVronline,n

λ^cost,n= PR

r=1

hQ

i

QTn

t=1P(ci,n,t = 1|Xi,n,t,Zz,n,b,Σb,Γr)ci,n,tλrcost,ni PR

r=1

Q

i

QTn

t=1P(ci,n,t = 1|Xi,n,t,Zz,n,b,Σb,Γr)ci,n,t were Γr corresponds toLVonline,nr andψri,n. Finally,

Cn=

Tn

X

t=1

1 Tn

λ^cost,nP

icosti,n,t+βbdelivery costG,E delivery costG,En,t P

icosti,n,t+delivery costGn,t,E Travel and delivery time are fixed coefficients = =

(45)

Appendix: Daily scheduling data

• Average MIV costs: 0.17 CHF/km (base scenario) → 1.77 CHF/km (scenario 4)

• Average distance traveled: 60 km (base scenario) →11 km (scenario 4)

012345Average MIV km cost [CHF/km]

B S1 S2 S3 S4

050100150200250300Traveled distance by MIV [km]

B S1 S2 S3 S4

(46)

Appendix: Mobility tool ownership data

• Average MIV costs: 0.25 CHF/km (base scenario) → 1.14 CHF/km (scenario 4)

• Average distance traveled: 9’900 km (base scenario)→ 6’610 km (scenario 4)

0.511.522.5Average MIV km cost [CHF/km]

B S1 S2 S3 S4

010,00020,00030,00040,00050,00060,000Traveled distance by MIV [km]

B S1 S2 S3 S4

(47)

Appendix: Daily distance; by mode

020406080100Daily distance [in % relative to base scenario]

Base Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4

(48)

Appendix: Yearly distance; by mode

020406080100Yearly distance [in % relative to base scenario]

Base Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4

Small car Medium car Large car

(49)

Appendix: Adaptations in mobility tool ownership

020406080100a) Car fleet [% rel. to base scenario] Base Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4

Small car Medium car Large car

MPV Company car

020406080100b) Fuel type [% rel. to base scenario] Base Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4

Gasoline Diesel Gas

Electric Hybrid

20406080100 020406080100120d) Costs [% rel. to base scenario]

Base Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4

(50)

Appendix: Modeling framework adaptations in car usage

Exponential regression model accounting for panel structure (EMIX):

yn,t = expα+Znρ+ψα,n+βen·log(xn,t)+ζn,t

βen= −exp(βcost +Znκ+ψβ,n

distn,0

dist0 ωdist

A draw ofψis calculated as ψrα,n ψβ,nr

!

= σα 0

σα,β σβ

!

· ηαr ηrβ

!

From this follows that Var(ψα,n) =σα2, Var(ψβ,n) =σ2α,β+σβ2 and Cov(ψα,n, ψβ,n) =σα·σα,β

(51)

Appendix: Estimation results (adaptation in car usage)

BASE DIST USER EMIX

# estimated parameters 3 4 13 16

# respondents 163 163 163 163

# choice observations 741 741 741 741

# draws 4000

R2 0.11 0.57 0.63 0.82

LLfinal 4010.39 3747.20 3696.99 3573.68

AICc 8026.93 7502.65 7422.42 7183.08

# estimated parameters 3 4 9 12

# households 165 165 165 165

# choice observations 821 821 821 821

# draws 4000

R2 0.02 0.46 0.54 0.95

LLfinal 2885.36 2642.64 2577.22 2015.49

(52)

Appendix: Cost elasticities (adaptation in car usage)

• All cost elasticity main effects significant (p <0.01)

• EMIX: Substantial amount of unobserved heterogeneity

• Daily scheduling: Elasticities are larger in all model specifications

• Results strongly affected by the inclusion of covariates; decreasing elasticities for increasing distance traveled in the base scenario

• EMIX: Similar relative, but decreasing magnitudes compared to BASE model

BASE DIST USER EMIX N

Medianbn −0.47 −0.27 −0.26 −0.37 163

Meanbn −0.47 −0.34 −0.36 −0.42

IQR (0.0) (0.30) (0.35) (0.29)

Medianbn −0.16 −0.24 −0.23 −0.13 165

Meanbn −0.16 −0.29 −0.27 −0.19

IQR (0.0) (0.27) (0.25) (0.12)

(53)

Appendix: Further research (related to current dataset)

• Mobility tool ownership RP model

– Investigate preferences and substitution patterns

– Integrate in the mode/route choice model (self-selection) – Modification of availability conditions

• Savings rate in time-use model – Savings now part ofEf2

– Decrease in the median VoL by about 7%

• Interrelations between travel behavior and ICT usage – Based on diary data (RP)

– Comparison/validation of results obtained from the shopping choice model

• Inclusion of attitudes (now only in shopping choice model) – Better representation of the decision process?

(54)

Appendix: Further research (general)

• Finer grained distinction of activities and expenditures – Committed vs. freely chosen

– Secondary activities (during travel, at home, etc.)

• Better tailored research design to disentangle mode and user-type effects – Self-selection still present (at the individual and/or trip-level)?

– Suggestion: Additional route choice tasks for different modes/trip purposes

• Context-dependency of results

– Example: Travel vs. shopping vs. delivery cost sensitivity – Important for valuation studies

• More sophisticated research design to investigate shopping channel preferences – More relaxed assumptions (product categories, trip chaining, etc.)

(55)

Appendix: Main lessons learned

• Focus groups: Which attributes are important?

• Reduction in response burden, more specific research design

• Better address respondents who are less willing to participate (saliency effects)

• Inclusion of traditional modes (e.g. car) in SP experiments

• Within-subject designs (trip purpose, distance, shopping purpose, etc.)

• Avoid necessity to impute based on external datasets (e.g. fixed income)

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

In urban district subcentres and inner city centres in large cities with high population densities custom- ers’ trips are to a large extent conducted using envi- ronmentally

The combined model under development proceeds in a nested fashion from modelling basic life- style decisions of individuals as a function of demographic development, career dynamics

As a result, the model, using fuzzy mathematical pro- gramming and a trade-off between the trains’ energy con- sumption and the travel time, and given the available time limit,

Moreover, it is shown that that the travel time distribution tends to be less skewed for higher congestion levels, and that the covariance between adjacent links seems to

In this paper, we have discussed how income and time can enter a discrete choice model in a microeconomically consistent way, emphasizing the necessity of assuming

We take the whole of this body of work as read, in what we present here, for the simple reason that we do not have the time to repeat it. We do not repeat it also because we have

Bayesian posterior prediction and meta-analysis: an application to the value of travel time savings.

In the following section we investigate what figure can be placed on W l lower boundaries of the welfare effects of travel time saving, and we asses the impact of a change in