• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Qantitative stability for scenario-based stochastic programs

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Qantitative stability for scenario-based stochastic programs"

Copied!
6
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

SCENARIO-BASED STOCHASTIC PROGRAMS

Jitka Dupacova

Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics, Charles University Sokolovska 83, 186 75 Prague, Czech Republic

e-mail: dupacova@karlin.m.cuni.cz Werner Romisch

Institute of Mathematics, Humboldt University, Unter den Linden 6, D-10099 Berlin, Germany e-mail: romisch@mathematik.hu-berlin.de

Abstract

General quantitative stability results for stochastic pro- grams are formulated in terms of probability metrics, spec- ied to scenario-based stochastic programs and applied to a bond portfolio management problem.

AMS classi cation: 90C15, 90C31, 60K30, 90C08 Key words: Probability metrics, stochastic programs, sta- bility wrt. probability measure, random recourse, discrete distributions, application

1 INTRODUCTION

Stability and sensitivity studies for stochastic programs have been motivated by an incomplete information about the probability measure through which the stochastic pro- gram is formulated and also by the eorts in designing various discretization and approximation schemes needed in connection with the development and evaluation of al- gorithms. The solved real life stochastic programs are very complex in numerical procedures, one uses their spe- cic structure and is interested in robust solutions: Small changes in the input (in our case mainly perturbations of the probability measure) are supposed to cause only small changes of the output (the optimal value, the set of optimal solutions). Evidently, such requirements can be cast under quantitative stability analysis, see for instance 1], 3] and references therein, 6], 10], 11] and 15]:

For a general stochastic program with a xed con- straint set

minimize EPf(

x

!) on a set X Rn (1)

whereP is a xed probability measure on ( B) belong- ing to a class P, with EP the corresponding expecta- tion operator,X Rn a given nonempty closed set and

f :X!R1 a given function, denote

'(P) = inf

x2X E

P

f(

x

!) (2)

the optimal value and

(P) = argmin

x2X E

P

f(

x

!)f

x

2Xjf(

x

P) ='(P)g (3) the solution set. To adapt the general quantitative sta- bility approaches means to select a metric distance dof probability measures which is suitable from the point of view of the structure of the considered stochastic pro- gram and/or of the particular type of approximation of probability measure P for to get a Lipschitz (or Holder) property of the optimal value

d(P P0)<)j'(P);'(P0)j<K

and possibly also a Lipschitz (or Holder) property of the Hausdor distance of the corresponding solution sets with respect to perturbations of P measured by d naturally, the Lipschitz (or Holder) constants depend on the chosen metricd.

The rst results concerning the optimal value can be found in 12]. Special assumptions are needed for to ex- tend these results to the optimal solutions. A Holder sta- bility result for solution sets of two-stage stochastic pro- grams with random right-hand side is obtained in 10]. It is formulated in terms of Wasserstein metric on all prob- ability measures having nite rst moments (and appear- ing as metric 1 in Section 2). The result is essentially based on a strong convexity property of the expected re- course function which is now well understood, cf. 14].

Later it has been claried in 15] and 11] that second or- der growth conditions for the objective function around the solution set lead to (upper) Lipschitzian stability re- sults for two-stage models. Unfortunately, such growth

(2)

conditions are only available in special situations (cf. also Section 2). Therefore it is expedient to investigate also quantitative stability for the sets of"-optimal solutions

"(P) =";argmin

x2X E

P f(

x

!)

=f

x

2XjEPf(

x

!)'(P) +"g (4) which hold true under more general circumstances (cf.

2]), an idea suggested in 13].

For the purposes of an algorithmic solution, the pre- vailing approximation technique is discretization of the initial probability measure: It is replaced by a discrete probability measure concentrated in a nite numbers of atoms, called scenarios. To design an approximation which is representative enough and such that the obtained so- lution enjoys plausible robustness properties is of a great importance. Quantitative stability results for these scena- rio-basedprograms may help to quantify the desirable ro- bustness properties also in rather complicated instances of stochastic programs with random recourse.

The success and applicability of the quantitative sta- bility results depend essentially on an appropriate choice of the probability metric used to measure the perturba- tions in the model input.

Example

. Consider the well known newsboy problem:

The newsboy sells newspapers for the costceach. Be- fore he starts selling, he has to buy the daily supply at the cost b a paper, c > b > 0: The demand is random and the unsold newspapers are returned without refund at the end of the day. How many newspapers should he buy?Assume that the demand is random with a known dis- crete distributionP concentrated at S points!1 ::: !S of a closed interval D1 D2] D1 > 0 with probabilities

p

s

>0 s= 1 ::: S Psps= 1. The problem is min

x0 E

P

f(x !) := (b;c)x+cX

s p

s(x;!s)+] Let an additional scenario! 2 D1 D2] be taken into account it corresponds to the degenerated probability measure Q = ! . The considered perturbed problem is related to a probability measure carried by the ini- tial scenarios!s s= 1 ::: S and by!. Assuming that the proportions between the initial probabilities ps s = 1 ::: S are kept we can specify this probability mea- sure as P = (1;)P +Q where 2 (0 1) is the probability of !. Evidently, the dierence between the initial and the perturbed objective values EPf(x !);

E

P

f(x !) =(EPf(x !);EQf(x !)) can be non-zero only on the interval D1 D2] and at eachx2D1 D2], its value depends on the probability of the additional sce- nario and on the dierence of the two objective functions

E

P

f(x !) EQf(x !) = f(x !). It is easy to bound the dierences of the values of the random objectives

f(x !) := (b;c)x+c(x;!)+ for two dierent real- izations:

jf(x !);f(x !0)j=cj(x;!)+;(x;!0)+jcj!;!0j8x so that the dierence of the two considered objective func-(5) tions

jE

P

f(x !);EQf(x !)j=cjX

s p

s(x;!s)+;(x;!)+j

c X

s p

s j!

s

;!

j (6)

The dierence between the function values depends obviously on the position of the additional scenario with respect to the initial ones. Let us have a look how is this fact reected by common distances of the one-dimensional probability measures.

LetF Gdenote the distribution functions associated withP Q. The Kolmogorov (or uniform metric)

d

K(P Q) := sup

t2R

jF(t);G(t)j equals

maxXs

j=1 p

j 1;Xs

j=1 p

j] if!2(!s !s+1) for somes and equals 1 otherwise.

Contrary to our expectations and the above results the Kolmogorov distance does not distinguish the magni- tude of the (positive) distance of the additional scenario from the convex hull of the initial ones! The least inu- ential additional scenario!2(!1 !S) should minimize the maximal value of Psj=1pj 1;Psj=1pj], a condition which is fullled for median ~! of the distributionP.

An important class of probability metrics in our con- text, are the Fortet-Mourier metricsp p1 which are dened in Section 2. Here we use the explicit formulas which are available for p in the one-dimensional case.

With the notation from above, it holds that (cf. Chapter 5 in 7])

p(P Q) =Z +1

;1

maxf1 jtjp;1gjF(t);G(t)jdt The metric 1 forms theL1-counterpart of the Kolmogo- rov metrics and is called (L1-) Wasserstein or Kantorovich metric. Similarly as for the Kolmogorov metric we have

1(P P) =1(P Q) and

1(P Q) =XS

j=1 p

j j!

j

;!

j

(3)

Notice that the distance between the additional scenario

!

and all original ones is taken into account and that the least inuential additional scenario coincides again with the median ~! ofP: For!2D1 D2],

X

j p

j j!

j

;!j~ 1(P Q)maxfEP!;D1 D2;EP!g: The next section summarizes the general quantita- tive stability results and provides their specication to scenario-based programs. The last section is devoted to an application to a bond portfolio management problem.

2 QUANTITATIVE STABILITY

RESULTS

We assume that the constraint setX is convex and closed, and that the functionf :X;!R1has the properties thatf( !) is convex for each!andf(

x

) is measurable for each

x

. Then the objective function

x

7!EPf(

x

!) :=Z

f(

x

!)P(d!) (7)

is convex onRnfor any probability measureP(on ( B)) such that (7) is nite. Later we only consider probability measures having this property.

The structure of the convex program (1) suggests to consider a probability semimetric of the form

d

F(P Q) := supfj

Z

f(!)(P(d!);Q(d!))j:f 2Fg whereF:=ff(

x

) :

x

2Xgis the class of all measurable(8) functions from toR1 that appear as integrands in (7).

The probability distance dF(P Q) is nite whenever P andQbelong to the set

P

F() :=fQ: sup

f2F j

Z

f(!)Q(d!)j<1g of probability measures (on ( B)) satisfying a uniform moment condition with respect toF.

Now, (1) is regarded as a convex parametric program with parameterP belonging to the semimetric space (PF() dF): The following stability result is a conse- quence of a more general perturbation theorem in 8].

Theorem 1.

In addition to the general assumptions, let

(P) be nonempty and bounded, P 2 PF() and the function

x

7! EPf(

x

!) be locally Lipschitzian on X. Then the solution set mappingis (Berge) upper semi- continuous at P and there exist constants L > 0 >

0 such that (Q) is nonempty and j'(P);'(Q)j

Ld

F(P Q) wheneverQ2PF() anddF(P Q)<:

Upper semicontinuity of at P means that for any

>0 there exists a =()>0 such that whenever

Q2P

F() anddF(P Q)< supx2(Q)d(

x

(P))<:

Of course, it would be desirable to quantify the semiconti- nuity behavior of , i.e., to derive an explicit representa- tion of the function() (e.g. of the form() = (=K)k with constantsk1 andK>0). To obtain such quanti- tative stability results, it is well known that growth con- ditions for the objective function EPf( !) near (P) play an important role. So far growth conditions have been explored only for stochastic programs with linear recourse and random right-hand sides or certain situa- tions of random technology matrices (14], 11]). Besides further conditions, the existence of a density to P be- ing positive on certain sets related to (P) is decisive for growth conditions in two-stage models. Since we are interested in models with random recourse and also in purely atomic measures P, these results do not apply.

Fortunately, the set of "-optimal solutions "(P) of (1) enjoys a much better stability behavior when perturbing the probability measureP.

Theorem 2.

Adopt the setting of Theorem 1. Then, for any "0 >0 there exists a constant ^L >0 such that for each"2(0 "0) the estimate

d

H("(P) "(Q))(^L=")dF(P Q) holds wheneverQ2PF() anddF(P Q)<":

(Here dH denotes the Hausdor distance on subsets of

R n.)

The result is taken from 13]. Its proof is based on estimates for "-optimal solution sets of convex programs (cf. Theorem 7.69 of 9] or 2]) and on further properties of level sets. It is worth mentioning that the Lipschitzian stability result for " at P is valid without assuming a growth condition for EPf( !) and, hence, applies to many convex stochastic programs.

It is also useful to note that both theorems remain valid true if the class F of measurable functions from ( B) toR1is replaced by a suitable larger class ^FF leading to favorable properties of the distances dF (e.g.

to nice representations or explicit formulas). For two- stage stochastic programs, classes of locally Lipschitzian functions with a prescribed growth of Lipschitz moduli are of particular interest. We assume in the following that is a subset of a Euclidean space and B is the- algebra of Borel sets relative to . We denote byFpwith

p1 the class of real-valued functionsf on satisfying the Lipschitzian property

jf(!);f(~!)jmaxf1 k!kp;1 k!k~ p;1gk!;!k~ for all ! !~ 2 and by Pp() the class of all proba- bility measures Qon ( B) havingp-th order moments,

(4)

i.e., Rk!kpQ(d!)< 1: Then the distance p(P Q) :=

d

Fp(P Q) is called Fortet-Mourier metric and (p Pp()) forms a metric space. The metricp enjoys a well devel- oped duality theory and convergence analysis (cf. 7]). In particular, the following dual representation ofpis valid:

p(P Q) = inffZ

maxf1 k!kp;1 k!k~ p;1g

k!;!kR~ (d! d!~)g

over all Borel probability measuresRon such that

R(B);R(B) =P(B);Q(B)8B2B(cf. Chapter 5 in 7]). A consequence of this result for :=R1 is the explicit formula forp that is used in Section 1.

The next result is a conclusion from Theorem 2 in case of discrete probability measures and of integrandsf(

x

) that satisfy a certain Lipschitz property.

Theorem 3.

Adopt the setting of Theorem 2 and let

P be a discrete probability measure on ( B) having the formP =PSi=1pi!i:Assume that there exist constants

p1 and Lf >0 such that the function (Lf);1f(

x

)

belongs toFpfor each

x

2X. Then, for any"0>0 there exists a constantL>0 such that for each "2(0 "0) the estimate

d

H("(P) "(Q))

L

"

inf

8

<

: S

X

i=1

~

S

X

j=1

ij k!

i

;!~jkmaxf1 k!ikp;1 k!~jkp;1g

9

=

subject to (9)

ij

20 1] XS

i=1

~

S

X

j=1

ij = 1 and

S

X

i=1!i2B

(

~

S

X

j=1

ij

;p

i) =

~

S

X

j=1~!j2B

(XS

i=1

ij

;q

j)8B2B holds wheneverQis a probability measure on ( B) hav- ing the formQ=PSj=1~ qj!~j and the propertyp(P Q)<

"

L

f :

Proof: Let"0 >0: We choose ^L> 0 as in Theorem 2 and select some"2(0 "0):Then Theorem 2 implies that

d

H("(P) "(Q))LL^ f

"

p(P Q)

wheneverp(P Q)< L"f where we used thatdF(P Q)

L

f

p(P Q):Due to the duality result forp, we have that

p(P Q)

Z

maxf1 k!kp;1 k!k~ p;1gk!;! kR~ (d! d!~)

holds for any probability measureRon of the form

R=PSi=1PSj=1~ ij!i!~j such that for anyB 2B

R(B);R(B) =XS

i=1

~

S

X

j=1

ij(!i(B);!~j(B))

=P(B);Q(B) =XS

i=1 p

i

!

i(B);

~

S

X

j=1 q

j

~

!

j(B): Taking the inmum subject to all such ij 2 0 1] and putting L:= ^LLf completes the proof.

2

The theorem provides an estimate for the Hausdor distance of "-optimal sets to (1) associated with two dis- crete probability measures in terms of the optimal value of a certain linear program. This estimate can be exploited to develop procedures for deleting scenarios of a given dis- crete probability measure or for studying the inuence of certain scenarios to changes of the problem. To discuss this in more detail, let P =PSi=1pi!i play the role of a discrete approximation to a certain original probability measure. P might be obtained by a suitable statistical es- timation procedure based on a nite (but large) sample.

Hence, one might wish to reduce that large numberS of scenarios!1 ::: !S in order to obtain moderately sized programs in practical applications. Deleting the scenario

!

k ofP could be done if the distancedH("(P) "(Qk)) is small, where Qk =PSj=1j6=kqj!j with properly cho- sen probabilitiesqj. Theorem 3 indicates that minimizing the optimal value of the linear program in the right-hand side of the estimate (9) (with ~S=S;1 f!~1 ::: !~S;1g=

f!

1 ::: !

k ;1

!

k +1 ::: !

S

g) subject to all weights qj 2 0 1] Pjqj = 1 is such an appropriate choice. A strat- egy for deleting scenarios could then be based on repeat- ing this argument successively. Finally, we study the in- uence of an additional scenario!2 by looking at the probability measureP= (1;)P+Q whereQ=! and 2 (0 1), cf. 4]. For small > 0 Theorem 3 provides the estimate

d

H("(P) "(P)) L

"

p(P P) = L

"

p(P Q)

L

"

S

X

i=1 p

i k!

i

;!

kmaxf1 k!ikp;1 k!kp;1g (10) where (10) contains the explicit solution of the linear pro- gram in (9). The least inuential additional scenario! then corresponds to the minimizer of the function in (10) subject to !2:

(5)

3 AN APPLICATION

The main purpose of the considered bond portfolio man- agement problem is to preserve the value of a bond port- folio of a risk averse or risk neutral institutional investor over time. It has been formulated as a multiperiod two- stage scenario-based stochastic program with complete random recourse (e.g., 5]). The main random element is the evolution of the short interest rate over time which is regarded as the only factor that drives the prices of the considered default free government bonds:

Given a sequence of equilibrium future short term in- terest rates rt valid for the time interval (t t+ 1] t = 0 ::: T ;1 the fair price of the j-th bond at time t just after the coupon was paid equals the total cashow

f

j

=t+1 ::: T generated by this bond in subsequent time instances discounted tot:

jt(

r

) = XT

=t+1 f

j

;1

Y

h=t

(1 +rh);1 (11) whereT is greater or equal to the time to maturity.

In formulation of the stochastic program one works with a suitable discrete distribution of theT - dimensional vector

r

of the short ratesrt t = 0 ::: T;1, wherer0 (the rate valid in the rst period) is known. The possi- ble nitely many realizations of

r

are called scenarios we shall index them as

r

s s= 1 ::: Sand assign them prob- abilitiesps >0 s= 1 ::: S Psps = 1. Generation of scenarios is a rather demanding estimation, callibration and sampling procedure. The applied input distribution is thus burdened by various inherent errors and our pri- mal goal is to analyze the inuence of these errors on the obtained optimal decisions and on the optimal value of the portfolio.

We denote

j = 1 ::: J indices of the considered bonds and Tj the dates of their maturitiesT = maxjTj.

t= 0 ::: T0the considered discretization of the plan- ning horizon

b

j

0 the initial holdings (in face value) of bondj

b

0

0 the initial holding in riskless asset

f s

jt cashow generated from bond j at time t under scenariosexpressed as a fraction of its face value

s

jt and sjt are the selling and purchasing prices of bondj at time t for scenarios obtained from the corre- sponding fair prices (8) by adding the acrued interestAsjt and by subtracting or adding scenario independent trans- action costs and spread the initial pricesj0 andj0 are known, i. e., scenario independent

x

j

=y

j are face values of bondj purchased/sold at the beginning of the planning period, at t = 0 xsjt=yjts are the corresponding values for periodt under scenarios.

z

j0 is the face value of bondj held in portfolio after the initial decisions xj yj have been made zjts are the corresponding holdings for period tunder scenarios.

The rst-stage decision variables xj yj zj0 are non- negative,

y

j+zj0=bj+xj 8j (12)

y +

0 +X

j

j0 x

j=b0+X

j

j0 y

j (13)

where the auxilliary nonnegative variabley0+ denotes the surplus.

Provided that an initial trading strategy determined by feasible scenario independent rst-stage decision vari- ables xj yj y+0 (and zj0) for all j has been accepted, the subsequent second-stage scenario dependent decisions have to be made in an optimal way regarding the goal of the model, i. e., to maximize the nal wealth subject to constraints on conservation of holdings and rebalancing the portfolio:

maximize VT0s :=X

j

s

jT0 z

s

jT0+yT0+s;yT0;s (14) subject to

z s

jt+yjts =zjt;1s +xsjt8j 1tT0 (15)

X

j

s

jt y

s

jt+X

j f

jt z

s

jt;1+ (1;1+rst;1)y+st;1+y;st =

X

j

s

jt x

s

jt+ (1 +2+rst;1)y;st;1+y+st 1tT0 (16)

x s

jt

0 yjts 0 zjts 0 yt;s0 y+st 08j 1tT0 with y0;s= 0 y+s0 =y0+ zj0s =zj08j the auxilliary vari-(17) ablesyt+s=yt;s describe the (unlimited) lending /borrow- ing possibilities for period t under scenario s and with parameters 1 0 2 > 0 1 xed according to the background of the solved problem.

With VT0(

x y z

0 y0+

r

s) the corresponding maximal value of the second-stage scenario subproblem (14)-(17), the full stochastic program can be now written in the form which allows to apply the general results of Section 2: The probability measure P = PSs=1psrs, the vec- tor of the original decision variables

x

!

x y z

0 y+0],

the set of feasible solutionsX is dened by nonnegativity constraints on all rst-stage variables and by constraints (12){(13), the random objective function f(

x

!) !

U(VT0(

x y z

0 y0+

r

)) with U a concave nondecreasing utility function. (The symbol ! relates the notation used in Section 2 to that used in the application.) No- tice that set of feasible rst-stage solutions is nonempty and bounded and that the function VT0(

r

) is concave

(6)

in

x y z

0 y0+ for any

r

2RT:In this notation, the con- sidered stochastic program maxx2XEPf(

x

!) reads

maximize XS

s=1 p

s

U(VT0(

x y z

0 y0+

r

s)) (18)

subject to nonnegativity constraints on all variables and subject to (12){(13).

The stochastic program (18) obviously ts into the setting of Section 2. In order to apply the quantitative stability results of Section 2 to study the behavior of (18), we introduce the classF of relevant integrands as

F:=fU(VT0(

x y z

0 y+0 )) :

x y z

0 y0+ are feasibleg and the semimetricdFon the classPF(RT) of probability measures as in Section 2. Moreover, let"(P) be the set of "-optimal solutions to (18). Then Theorem 2 applies and we obtain the following stability result for (18).

Theorem 4.

^ For any "0 > 0 there exists a constant

L>0 such that for each"2(0 "0) the estimate

d

H("(P) "(Q)) L^

"

d

F(P Q)

holds wheneverQis another discrete probability measure onRT anddF(P Q)<":

For the proof it remains to note that all discrete prob- ability measures having nite support in RT belong to

P

F(RT) and that the assumptions of Theorem 1 are sat- ised.

Of course, it would be desirable to identify classes of functions (like the class Fp in Section 2), that contain

F and allow dual representations for the corresponding metrics. So far this remains an open problem.

4 BIBLIOGRAPHY

1] Artstein, Z., Sensitivity with respect to the underlying information in stochastic programs, JCAM

56

(1994), 127{136.

2] Attouch, H. and Wets, R. J.-B., Quantitative stability of variational systems: III. -approximate solutions, Math. Progr.

61

(1993), 197{214.

3] Dupa!cova, J., Stability and sensitivity - analysis for stochastic programming, Annals of Oper. Res.

27

(1990), 115{142.

4] Dupa!cova, J., Scenario-based stochastic programs: Re- sistance with respect to sample, Annals of Oper. Res.

64

(1996), 21{38.

5] Dupa!cova, J., Stability properties of a bond portfolio management problem, paper prepared for APMOD98, March 1998, Cyprus.

6] Ka!nkova, V., On stability in two-stage stochastic non- linear programming, in: Asymptotic Statistics (P. Man- dl and M. Hu!skova, eds.), Physica Verlag, Heidelberg 1994, 329{440.

7] Rachev, S. T., Probability Metrics and the Stability of Stochastic Models. Wiley, Chichester 1991.

8] Rachev, S. T. and Romisch, W., Quantitative stability of stochastic programs: The approach via probability metrics, manuscript, 1998.

9] Rockafellar, R. T. and Wets, R. J.-B., Variational Analysis. Springer, Berlin 1997.

10] Romisch, W. and Schultz, R., Stability analysis for stochastic programs, Annals of Oper. Res.

30

(1991), 241{266.

11] Romisch, W. and Schultz, R., Lipschitz stability for stochastic programs with complete recourse, SIAM J.

Optimization

6

(1996), 531{547.

12] Romisch, W. and Walkobinger, A., Obtaining conver- gence rates for approximations in stochastic program- ming, in: Parametric Optimization and Related Top- ics, J. Guddat et al. (eds.), Akademie-Verlag, Berlin 1987, 327{343.

13] Romisch, W. and Wets, R. J.-B., Asymptotics of solu- tion sets in stochastic programming, lecture presented at the 4th World Congress of the Bernoulli Society, Vienna, Aug. 26{31, 1996.

14] Schultz, R. Strong convexity in stochastic programs with complete recourse, JCAM

56

(1994), 3{22.

15] Shapiro, A., Quantitative stability in stochastic pro- gramming, Math. Progr.

67

(1994), 99{108.

Acknowledgement

. The rst author was partly sup- ported by the Grant Agency of the Czech Republic under grants No. 201/96/0230 and 402/96/0631, the second au- thor by the German Research Foundation under grant No.

Ro 1006/5-1 with the joint research held up also within the agreement on collaboration between the Charles Uni- versity, Prague and the Humboldt University, Berlin.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

noted, “No country, besides Germany, was involved in massacres of Jews on such a scale”. 3 The systematic deportation and killing of Jews was carried out by the Roma- nian army

Literary examples as an argument and explication of some philosophical concepts have also been employed by Filip Bardziński in his comprehensive paper on transformations

Building regional water use scenarios consistent with global Shared Socioeconomic Pathways Journal Name.. Total Environmental

A direct application of the preceding lemmas yields the upper bound. As mentioned in the Introduction, all the results obtained in this section have their

In the second part, I present seven ‚strategies of commemoration’ (Documenting, Interpreting, Investigating, Exhibiting of fragmentarized Memories, Swearing/staging of Trauma,

Wenn im hier vorliegenden Entwurf für konkrete Methoden für Bedeutungs-Begründungs-Analysen zunächst nicht auf Anforderungen bezüglich eines Forschungsarrangements eingegangen

One of the central properties of the ISDS estimate is that it admits an ISDS Lyapunov function, which not only characterizes ISDS as a qualitative property (the qualitative

Our considerations lead to a new variant of ISS, called input–to–state dy- namical stability (ISDS), which is based on using a one–dimensional dynamical system for building the class