• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Economicgrowthanddebt:asimplifiedmodel Krouglov,Alexei MunichPersonalRePEcArchive

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Economicgrowthanddebt:asimplifiedmodel Krouglov,Alexei MunichPersonalRePEcArchive"

Copied!
22
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Economic growth and debt: a simplified model

Krouglov, Alexei

21 June 2015

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/65178/

MPRA Paper No. 65178, posted 22 Jun 2015 06:14 UTC

(2)

Economic Growth and Debt: A Simplified Model

Alexei Krouglov

alexkrouglov@gmail.com

(3)

Economic Growth and Debt: A Simplified Model

ABSTRACT

Presented is a mathematical model of single-product economy where an investment and debt are used to alter the demand for and supply of product. Explored is the dynamics of a nominal economic growth and decline. Examined are cases of a constant-rate growing debt and a constant-rate and constant-acceleration growing investment.

JEL Classification Numbers: E32, E51, E22 Keywords: debt, investment, modeling

(4)

1 Introduction

There are four enormously important concepts in the economics: demand, supply, investment, and debt.

Here I present a mathematical model, where I examine their interconnections and explore their impacts on the nominal economic growth and decline.

Below I describe a mathematical model of the market of single-product economy. Economic forces acting on the market represent inherent market forces of demand and supply complemented with the forces caused by an investment, debt and corresponding debt servicing. The market actions are expressed through the system of ordinary differential equations.

The model continues prior research for nominal economic growth and decline performed in Krouglov, 2014 and previous research for credit expansion and contraction carried out in Krouglov, 2015.

The presented model has mostly a theoretical value.

2 Single-Product Economy at the Undisturbed State

Concepts and methodology presented in this section are based on the framework of mathematical dynamics of economic systems developed in Krouglov, 2006; 2009.

When there are no disturbing economic forces, the market is in equilibrium position, i.e., the supply of and demand for product are equal, they are developing with a constant rate and a price of the product is fixed.

I assume the market had been in an equilibrium until time

tt

0, volumes of the product supply

V

S

  t

and demand

V

D

  t

on market were equal, and they both were developing with a constant rate

r

D0. The product price

P   t

at that time was fixed,

(5)

  

0

0

0

D D

D

t r t t V

V   

(1)

  t V   t

V

S

D (2)

  t P

0

P

(3)

where

V

D

  t

0

V

D0.

When the balance between the volumes of product supply and demand is broken, a market is experiencing economic forces, which act to bring the market to a new equilibrium position.

3 Constant-Rate Debt and Constant-Rate Investment

I present a model of single-product economy where both the credit and investment are increasing with constant rates.

According to this scenario, the credit expansion causes a debt growth where the amount of debt

S

D

  t

on

the market rises since time

tt

0 according to following formula,

     

 

0 0

0

, , 0

t t t t

t t t

S

D

D

(4)

where

S

D

  t  0

for

tt

0 and

D

 0

.

Correspondingly, the debt growth causes an increase of debt servicing cost

s

S

  t  

S

S

D

  t

,

S

 0

, where the accumulated amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

on the market rises according to following formula since time

tt

0,

    

 

0 2

0

0

2 , , 0

t t t t

t t t

S

S

S

D (5)

(6)

where

S

S

  t  0

for

tt

0 and

S

 0

.

Likewise, I assume the amount of investment

S

I

  t

on the market increases since time

tt

0 according to following formula,

     

 

0 0

0

, , 0

t t t t

t t t

S

I

I

(6)

where

S

I

  t  0

for

tt

0 and

I

 0

.

Economic forces trying to bring the market into a new equilibrium position are described by the following ordinary differential equations with regard to the volumes of product supply

V

S

  t

, demand

V

D

  t

, and

price

P   t

given the accumulated amounts of debt

S

D

  t

, debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

, and investment

  t

S

I on the market (see Krouglov, 2006; 2009; 2014; 2015),

   V   t V   t S   t S   t S   t

dt t dP

I S

D D

S

P

   

 

(7)

   

dt t dP dt

t V d

S S2

 

2

(8)

   

2 2 2

2

dt t P d dt

t V d

D

D

  

(9)

In Eqs. (7) – (9) above the values

P

, 

S

, 

D

 0

are constants and they characterize price inertness, supply inducement, and demand amortization correspondingly.

One may observe that a difference between the volumes of product demand and supply on the market is increasing, in the sense:

  t V   tS   t S   t S   tV   t V   t

V

D

S

I

D

S

D

S

if the sum of accumulated amount of investment

S

I

  t

and accumulated amount of debt

S

D

  t

exceeds the accumulated amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

:

S

I

  tS

D

  tS

S

  t

.

(7)

On the other hand, a difference between the volumes of product demand and supply on the market is decreasing, in the sense:

  t V   tS   t S   t S   tV   t V   t

V

D

S

I

D

S

D

S

if the sum of accumulated amount of investment

S

I

  t

and accumulated amount of debt

S

D

  t

goes

below the accumulated amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

:

S

I

  tS

D

  tS

S

  t

.

Thus, in the time interval

 

D S

D

t

I

t

t  

 

 2

0

0 an expansion of the product demand over supply

takes place, and in the time interval

t     t 

D S

D I

 2

0 a contraction of the product demand over

supply happens.

Let me introduce a new variable

D   t   V

S

  tV

D

  tS

D

  tS

S

  tS

I

  t

representing the volume of product surplus (or shortage) on the market. Therefore, behavior of

D   t

is described by the following equation for

tt

0,

      0

2

2

P D

P S

D t

S D

dt t dD dt

t D

d      

(10)

with the initial conditions,

D   t

0

 0

,

 

D

dt

I

t

dD

0

    

.

If one uses another variable

   

S P

D

t

S

D t

D  

 

1

, then Eq. (10) becomes,

 

1

 

1

  0

2 1

2

  D t

dt t dD dt

t D d

S P D

P

  

(11)

with the initial conditions,

 

S P

D

t

S

D  

 

0

1 ,

 

D

dt

I

t

dD

1 0

    

.

(8)

Similar to Eq. (10), the product price

P   t

is described by the following equation for

tt

0,

     

0

0

0

2

2

  

 

   

P t P t t

dt t dP dt

t P d

S D S S

D I S

P D

P

 

(12)

with the initial conditions,

P   t

0

P

0,

 

0

 0 dt

t

dP

.

Let me introduce variable

     

S D

S D S

D S S

D

I

t t

P t P t

P  

0 2 0

1

      

to simplify an

analysis of the product price behavior. The behavior of variable

P

1

  t

is described by the equation for

t

0

t

,

 

1

 

1

  0

2 1

2

  P t

dt t dP dt

t P d

S P D

P

  

(13)

with the initial conditions,

 

S D

S D S

D

t

I

P  

0 2

1

   

,

 

S D S

dt t dP

 

0

1 .

The behavior of solutions for

D

1

  t

and

P

1

  t

described by Eqs. (11) and (13) depends on the roots of the corresponding characteristic equations (Piskunov, 1965; Petrovski, 1966). Note that Eqs. (11) and (13) have the same characteristic equations.

When the roots of characteristic equation are complex-valued (i.e.,

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

) both the variable

  t

D

1 and variable

P

1

  t

experience damped oscillations for time

tt

0. When the roots of characteristic equation are real and different (i.e.,

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

) both the variable

D

1

  t

and variable

P

1

  t

don’t

(9)

oscillate for time

tt

0. When the roots of characteristic equation are real and equal (i.e.,

S P D

P

  

 

4

2 2

) both the variable

D

1

  t

and variable

P

1

  t

don’t oscillate for time

tt

0 as well.

It takes place

D

1

  t  0

and

P

1

  t  0

for

t  

if roots of characteristic equations are complex- valued (

P

D

P

S

4 

2 2

), real and different (

P

D

P

S

4 

2 2

), or real and equal (

P

D

P

S

4 

2 2

).

It takes place for the product surplus (shortage)

D   t

, for the product price

P   t

, for the product demand

  t

V

D , for the product supply

V

S

  t

, for the amount of debt

S

D

  t

, for the amount of debt servicing cost

  t

S

S , and for the amount of investment

S

I

  t

if

t 

,

 

S P

D

t

S

D  

 

(14)

   

S D

S D S

D I S

D

S

t t P

t

P  

2 0

0

   

(15)

     

S D

S D D I S D D D

S S D D

D

t r t t V

V  

 

 

 

 

2 2 0

0

0

     

 

 

(16)

       

D S S D S P

D S

D I S D D D

S D

S S D D I D

S

t r t t t t V

V

 

 

 

 

 

2 2

2 0 0 0

0

2

 

 

   

(17)

  tt t

0

S

I

 

I

(18)

  tt t

0

S

D

 

D

(19)

  

0

2

2 t t t

S

S

 

S

D

(20)

(10)

To analyze an economic growth I use the variable

E

D

      t P t r

D

t

where

   

dt t t dV

r

D

D , i.e., a

rate of nominal demand for the product, which roughly represents the product earning on the market.

I compare the variable

E

D

  t

, rate of nominal demand changed by the amount of debt

S

D

  t

, the amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

, and the amount of investment

S

I

  t

, with the variable

E

D

  t

~

, original rate

unchanged by the amounts of debt, debt servicing cost and investment, for

t  

,

    

 

 

 

 

      

S D

S D D D S S D S

D I S

D S

D

t t t P r

E  

 

 

0

2 0

0 and

E ~

D

  tP

0

r

D0.

Thus, if the amounts of debt

S

D

  t

and of investment

S

I

  t

are correspondingly increasing with a constant-rate

D

 0

and a constant-rate

I

 0

to advance an expansion of the product demand over supply on the market then the amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

is increasing with a constant- acceleration

S

D

 0

and ultimately causing an unrestricted decrease of the rate of nominal demand

  t

E

D with the passage of time.

We can estimate a decrease

e

D

  t

of the rate of nominal demand

E

D

  t

where

   

dt t t dE

e

D

D , i.e., the

decrease of the rate of nominal demand for product, which roughly represents the decrease of the product earning on market.

It takes place, for

t  

,

 

0

   0

 

 

S D

S D D S

D S

D

t r

e  

when

S

D

 0

.

(11)

The limitary value of variable

e

D

  t

doesn’t have extremal points in the region

S

D

 0

. In fact, the variable

e

D

  t

has maximal limitary value when 0

2

D D

S D

S

r

 

  

. Then, respectively for

t  

,

 

    0

4

max  1

D0 2

D

D

t r

e

.

Therefore, the limitary value of variable

e

D

  t

is always negative in the region

S

D

 0

. Maximum for the change of a rate of nominal demand for product,

max  e

D

  t

, is achieved outside of the region

 0

D S

, and is equal at the limit, for time

t  

,

      0

4

max  1

D0 2

D

D

t r

e

.

I will talk about economic implications of some results in a succeeding section.

4 Constant-Rate Debt and Constant-Acceleration Investment

I present a model of single-product economy where the credit is increasing with a constant rate and the investment is increasing with a constant acceleration.

According to this scenario, the credit expansion causes a debt growth where the amount of debt

S

D

  t

on

the market rises since time

tt

0 according to following formula,

     

 

0 0

0

, , 0

t t t t

t t t

S

D

D

(21)

where

S

D

  t  0

for

tt

0 and

D

 0

.

(12)

Correspondingly, the debt growth causes an increase of debt servicing cost

s

S

  t  

S

S

D

  t

,

S

 0

, where the accumulated amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

on the market rises according to following formula since time

tt

0,

    

 

0 2

0

0

2 , , 0

t t t t

t t t

S

S

S

D (22)

where

S

S

  t0

for

tt

0 and

S

 0

.

Likewise, I assume the amount of investment

S

I

  t

on the market increases since time

tt

0 according to following formula,

      

 

0 2

0 0

0

2 , , 0

t t t t t

t

t t t

S

I

I

I

 

(23)

where

S

I

  t  0

for

tt

0,

I

 0

, and

I

 0

.

Economic forces trying to bring the market into a new equilibrium position are described by the following ordinary differential equations with regard to the volumes of product supply

V

S

  t

, demand

V

D

  t

, and price

P   t

given the accumulated amounts of debt

S

D

  t

, debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

, and investment

  t

S

I on the market,

   V   t V   t S   t S   t S   t

dt t dP

I S

D D

S

P

   

 

(24)

   

dt t dP dt

t V d

S S2

 

2

(25)

   

2 2 2

2

dt t P d dt

t V d

D

D

  

(26)

(13)

One may observe that a difference between the volumes of product demand and supply on the market is increasing, in the sense:

  t V   tS   t S   t S   tV   t V   t

V

D

S

I

D

S

D

S

if the sum of accumulated amount of investment

S

I

  t

and accumulated amount of debt

S

D

  t

exceeds

the accumulated amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

:

S

I

  tS

D

  tS

S

  t

.

On the other hand, a difference between the volumes of product demand and supply on the market is decreasing, in the sense:

  t V   tS   t S   t S   tV   t V   t

V

D

S

I

D

S

D

S

if the sum of accumulated amount of investment

S

I

  t

and accumulated amount of debt

S

D

  t

goes below the accumulated amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

:

S

I

  tS

D

  tS

S

  t

.

Thus, if

S

D

 

I: in the time interval

 

I D S

D

t

I

t

t   

 

 2

0

0 an expansion of the product demand

over supply takes place, and in the time interval

  

  t

t

I D S

D I

 2

0 a contraction of the product

demand over supply happens. If

S

D

 

I then an expansion of the product demand over supply takes place in the entire time interval

t

0

t  

.

Let me introduce a new variable

D   t   V

S

  tV

D

  tS

D

  tS

S

  tS

I

  t

representing the volume of product surplus (or shortage) on the market. Therefore, behavior of

D   t

is described by the following equation for

tt

0,

      0

2

2

P D

P S

D t

I

S D

dt t dD dt

t D

d       

(27)

(14)

with the initial conditions,

D   t

0

 0

,

 

D

dt

I

t

dD

0

    

.

If one uses another variable

   

S P

D S

t

I

D t

D  

 

1

, then Eq. (27) becomes,

 

1

 

1

  0

2 1

2

  D t

dt t dD dt

t D d

S P D

P

  

(28)

with the initial conditions,

 

S P

D S

t

I

D  

 

0

1 ,

 

D

dt

I

t

dD

1 0

    

.

Similar to Eq. (27), the product price

P   t

is described by the following equation for

tt

0,

     

0

0

 0

2

2

 

 

      

P t P t t

dt t dP dt

t P d

S D S I S

D I S

P D

P

 

(29)

with the initial conditions,

P   t

0

P

0,

 

0

 0 dt

t

dP

.

Let me introduce variable

      

I S D

S D S

D S I S

D

I

t t

P t P t

P   

   

0 0 2

1 to

simplify an analysis of the product price behavior. The behavior of variable

P

1

  t

is described by the following equation for

tt

0,

 

1

 

1

  0

2 1

2

  P t

dt t dP dt

t P d

S P D

P

  

(30)

with the initial conditions,

  

I S D

S D S

D

t

I

P   

 

2

0

1 ,

 

S D S I

dt t dP

 

0

1 .

The behavior of solutions for

D

1

  t

and

P

1

  t

described by Eqs. (28) and (30) depends on the roots of the corresponding characteristic equations (Piskunov, 1965; Petrovski, 1966). Also Eqs. (28) and (30) have the same characteristic equations.

(15)

When the roots of characteristic equation are complex-valued (i.e.,

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

) both the variable

  t

D

1 and variable

P

1

  t

experience damped oscillations for time

tt

0. When the roots of characteristic equation are real and different (i.e.,

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

) both the variable

D

1

  t

and variable

P

1

  t

don’t oscillate for time

tt

0. When the roots of characteristic equation are real and equal (i.e.,

S P D

P

  

4

2 2

) both the variable

D

1

  t

and variable

P

1

  t

don’t oscillate for time

tt

0 as well.

It takes place

D

1

  t  0

and

P

1

  t  0

for

t  

if roots of characteristic equations are complex- valued (

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

), real and different (

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

), or real and equal (

P

D

P

S

4

2 2

).

It takes place for the product surplus (shortage)

D   t

, for the product price

P   t

, for the product demand

  t

V

D , for the product supply

V

S

  t

, for the amount of debt

S

D

  t

, for the amount of debt servicing cost

  t

S

S , and for the amount of investment

S

I

  t

if

t  

,

 

S P

D S

t

I

D  

 

(31)

    

I S D

S D S

D I S

D S

I

t t P

t

P   

     

0 0 2 (32)

        

I S D

S D D I S D D D

S I S D D

D

t r t t V

V   

 

 

 

 

 

 

  

0 0 0 22 (33)

       

  

I S D

S D S

P D S I D I S D D

D S I D

S I S D D I D S

V

t t t

t r

t V

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

    

2 2 0

2 0 0

0

2

(34)

(16)

  

0

 

0

2

2 t t t

t t

S

I

 

I

  

I

(35)

  tt t

0

S

D

 

D

(36)

  

0

2

2 t t t

S

S

 

S

D

(37)

To analyze an economic growth I use the variable

E

D

      tP tr

D

t

where

   

dt t t dV

r

D

D , i.e., a

rate of nominal demand for the product, which roughly represents the product earning on the market.

I compare the variable

E

D

  t

, a rate of nominal demand changed by the amount of debt

S

D

  t

, the amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

, and the amount of investment

S

I

  t

, with the variable

E

D

  t

~

,

original rate unchanged by the amounts of debt, debt servicing cost and investment, for

t  

,

        

 

  

 

 

   

 

I S D

S D D D S I S D S

D I S

D S I

D

t t t P r

E   

 

 

0

2 0

0 and

 

0 0

~

D

D

t P r

E

.

If the amount of debt

S

D

  t

is increasing with a constant rate

D

 0

and the amount of investment

  t

S

I is increasing with a constant-acceleration

I

 0

then resulting outcome depends on relationship between the acceleration of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

:

S

D

 0

, and the acceleration of investment

  t

S

I :

I

 0

.

If

S

D

 

I, the amount of debt servicing cost

S

S

  t

is going to exceed the amount of investment

  t

S

I and ultimately causes an unrestricted decrease of the rate of nominal demand

E

D

  t

with the

passage of time.

(17)

We can estimate a decrease

e

D

  t

of the rate of nominal demand

E

D

  t

where

   

dt t t dE

e

D

D , i.e., the

decrease of the rate of nominal demand for product, which roughly represents the decrease of the product earning on market.

It takes place, for

t  

,

 

0

    0

 

  

 

I S D

S D D S

D S I

D

t r

e   

when

S

D

 

I.

The limitary value of variable

e

D

  t

doesn’t have extremal points in the region

S

D

 

I. In fact, the variable

e

D

  t

has a maximal limitary value when 0

2

D D

S D S

I

r

 

  

. Respectively for

t  

,

 

    0

4

max  1

D0 2

D

D

t r

e

.

Therefore, the limitary value of variable

e

D

  t

is always negative in the region

S

D

 

I. Maximum for the change of a rate of nominal demand for product,

max  e

D

  t

, is achieved outside of the region

I D

S

 

 

, and is equal at the limit, for time

t  

,

      0

4

max  1

D0 2

D

D

t r

e

.

If D0

D S D S I D

S

r

 

   

, the amount of investment

S

I

  t

is going to exceed the amount of debt

servicing cost

S

S

  t

and

r

D

  t  0

. It ultimately causes an unrestricted increase of the rate of nominal demand

E

D

  t

with the passage of time.

We can estimate an increase

e

D

  t

of the rate of nominal demand

E

D

  t

, i.e., the increase of a rate of nominal demand for product, which roughly represents the increase of the product earning on market.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Abstract: This paper examines, in a one-good two-country Cournot competition model, the implication of European VAT reform on the nominal exchange rate parities which will be

Results showed that in case of a constant- accelerated continuous savings economy would experience a continuous steady economic growth in the long run only if acceleration rate

When there are no disturbing economic forces, financial market is in equilibrium position, i.e., the supply of and demand for financial product are equal, they are developing

The first stage is to counterbalance an impact on the markets of the external supply of products from external suppliers brought with a constant rate, which would cause a

When such balance between the money supply and demand is broken, financial market is experiencing the economic forces, which act to bring the market to a new equilibrium

The long-run results of ARDL model show that the effect of exchange rate volatility on economic growth is negative.. ECM estimate shows that approximately 22% of disequilibria from

Within the context of Post-Keynesian growth theory, the hypothesis that long-run growth is endogenous to demand is also at the basis of the approach advanced by León-Ledesma and

log(GDP ) it , to measure the one-time level effect from the reform, or the difference in the compound growth rates between the two periods, denoted by ∆g it , to measure