• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Fossil-fuels, bio-fuels and food: Raking priorities

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Fossil-fuels, bio-fuels and food: Raking priorities"

Copied!
22
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Fossil-fuels, bio-fuels and food: Raking priorities

Dias, Guilherme Leite da Silva and Guilhoto, Joaquim José Martins

University of São Paulo

2010

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30733/

MPRA Paper No. 30733, posted 05 May 2011 19:10 UTC

(2)

Guilherme Leite da Silva Dias

Department of Economics, FEA - University of São Paulo E-mail: guildias@usp.br

Joaquim José Martins Guilhoto

Department of Economics, FEA - University of São Paulo REAL, University of Illinois; and CNPq Scholar

E-mail: guilhoto@usp.br

Abstract

This paper deals with the question of the trade-offs between bio-fuels, fossil-fuels, and food. To do so an analysis is conducted taking into consideration the differences in relative prices and in the productive structure among the countries. The results shows that in general food puts a greater stress over the economies than energy does, and mainly in the developing economies. As a consequence of that, the possibilities for the growing use of bio-fuels is limited and restrict to countries where it is possible to have an expansion of bio-fuel production without compromising the production of food and without putting more stress over the environment. This, by its turn, restricts the possibilities for a world policy of bio-fuels with the consequence that bilateral agreements would be the dominant ones.

Key words: Fossil-Fuels, Bio-Fuels, Food, Productive Structure, Input-Output.

(3)

1. Is There a Possible Common Policy for Bio-fuels?

The answer is no, because bio-fuel demand and supply is commanded by a set of country specific restrictions. Rising food cost is a very sensitive issue for low income countries, also in countries that have experienced famine due to social or political upheavals. Global energy crisis increases average cost of energy everywhere but uncertainty about energy supply has many different forms according to the availability of alternative primary sources and access to traded complementary sources. Global Warming awareness is becoming another constraint on fossil fuels and energy efficiency but widely different between countries. A further complication draws upon the fact that those three restrictions are not independent, for any change in one of them as for instance the rising cost of oil, the impact upon food supply is negative and many countries will make more use of coal as an alternative source for thermal electricity.

The implications of biofuels production on emission of green house gases and the net effect of the substitution of fossil fuels cannot be underestimated. By the end of 2007 German government issued a draft of the biomass sustainability ordinance, with the inclusion of a first assessment of land use changes following recommendations from the IPCC report. Given a certain set of default values and the assumption that sugar cane and soybean expansion in Latin America comes from conversion of savannah soils to cropland, and palm oil in Southeast Asia from rainforest, an amazing set of results depicted in Figure 1 below, contributed to a halt on fiscal incentives to bio-fuel production in Germany and imports without previous certification.

Many other countries followed suit and to complicate matters further the bubble on food market prices created a dismal picture for bio-fuels. The two following sections deals with pricing bio-fuels as a substitute for fossil fuels and the wide dispersion between countries on the role of food and energy sectors suggesting that bilateral trade agreements is a better strategic alternative to Brazil than the current choice of a globally traded commodity.

(4)

Figure 1 - Green House Emissions by Alternative Bio-fuels

2. Trade Opportunities

In this section we address the issue of bio-fuels prospective trade opportunities or, in another way to put it, can bio-fuels become commodities regularly traded in spot and future markets?

Fossil fuels although traded regularly have a substantial share traded under long term contracts to give enough security on the issue of access, even though contracted price may fluctuate according to some formulae related to spot and future market references. The majority of fossil fuel reserves are state property or state controlled corporation’s property. Market uncertainty is not left to speculation by economic agents but handled as a national security affair consequently it is priced and supplied by a myriad of alternative structures in each nation. Average prices collected on an annual basis reflect this diversity as in Figure 2 below, domestic indirect taxation more than border tariff explains the dispersion between gasoline and diesel prices.

(5)

Figure 2 – WDI / Diesel & Gasoline Prices, 34 Countries.

Precos de Diesel e Gasolina-2004

POL

BEL

VEN SAU

CHN

DEU

USA BRA

IRN

NLD GBR

IDN

ZAF

IND AUS JPN

-0,20 0,00 0,20 0,40 0,60 0,80 1,00 1,20 1,40 1,60 1,80

0,00 0,20 0,40 0,60 0,80 1,00 1,20 1,40 1,60 1,80

gasolina diesel

This sample of 34 countries adds to 85% of the world consumption of energy.

The lowest prices are found in typical oil exporting economies, for a $0,20 per gallon of diesel gasoline is priced at $ 0,28; in a middle group of countries (Brazil and USA included), for a diesel of $ 0,60 gasoline is at $ 0,76; for the group of high priced liquid fuels, diesel goes for $1,20 and gasoline for $1,44. This is not the kind of price dispersion that we expect from a level playing field type of market structure but is a real picture of a crystallized diverse set of national regulated markets.

The current generation of biofuels consists of basic agricultural products subjected to well known transformation procedures, mostly fermentation and chemical reaction. It is essentially a joint production system of multiple products, that could be organized as a regular market system. Most used agricultural products- sugar cane, maize, wheat, soybean,….- have only been traded under a global market system since the Uruguay Round (1995), for fifty years after the II World War the spectrum of chronic starvation prevented most nations to abandon the objective of self sufficiency and protectionism. Against the uncertainty of agricultural production many countries have shown a preference for building stocks of basic food products and occasionally getting rid of their high cost of maintenance by exporting at subsidized prices. Food security was the main strategic goal; reluctantly many countries accepted the

(6)

uncertainties around market access in exchange for domestic inefficient production and failures in the pursuit of self sufficiency.

Price dispersion among basic agricultural commodities is not as wide as with fossil fuels but still far away from normally traded manufactured products. Figures 3, 4 and 5 show alternative ways for comparison. Excluding Japan, Korea and Nigeria (most protected agricultural markets) in a three fold range of prices we find 25 wheat producing countries (out of those 34 countries seen before), in a five fold range we include another 24 maize producing countries, and in a ten fold range we include 19 rice producing countries. Ten years after the Uruguay Round what we have is still a diverse set of national regulated markets

Figure 3 - FAO/Maize&Rice Prices for 19 Countries

Figure 4 – FAO / Maize & Wheat Prices, 25 Countries

Maize and Wheat-current prices US$, 2004

KORNGA

JPN

50 250 450 650 850 1050

50 250 450 650 850 1050 1250 wheat

maize

50 100 150 200 250

50 100 150 200 250 300

Maize and Wheat - Japan, Korea and Nigeria excluded

Maize and Rice- Japan, Korea and Nigeria excluded

0 50 100 150 200 250 300

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 550 600

rice maize

0 200 400 600 800 1000

0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200 1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1800 1900 2000 2100 2200 2300

rice

maizeMaize and Rice- current prices US$, 2004

(7)

Figure 5 – FAO / Rice & Wheat Prices, 24 Countries

Recent market volatility is reminding us of how limited is food security under a free market framework. Global demand for food was raised to unprecedented level due to the dominant role played by emerging economies and global supply did not respond in order to keep inventories at a safe level; Figure 6 reports data on demand by group of countries, demand for corn by ethanol producers, and on global supply of major crops.

Figure 6 - World Demand and Supply of Major Crops

Inventories decreased for almost a decade, prices became more volatile since 2002/2003 and extremely speculative in 2007/2008 when a few countries raised export

NGA KOR

JPN

100 300 500 700 900 1100 1300 1500 1700 1900 2100 2300

50 250 450 650 850 1050 1250

Rice and Wheat- current prices US$, 2004

50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 550

50 100 150 200 250 300

Rice and Wheat, Japan, Korea and Nigeria excluded

Food crisis is a chance to reform global agriculture, Martin Wolf, FT-April 29, 2008.

(8)

restrictions (Central Europe on wheat, and South Asian countries on rice), Figure 7 below. One explanation points to a major fault in WTO regulation, because it lacks in safeguard clauses when global inventories are at extremely low levels, requiring from major suppliers’, government supported prices above international market prices in order to induce inventory accumulation. There is no built in incentive for individual countries to behave in a manner consistent with global common interest, they have to bare the costs of inventory build up and collect no benefit from doing it.

Figure 7 - End of the Year Inventories of Coarse Grains.

Ending Stocks of Coarse Grains*

0 50 100 150 200 250

94/95 95/96

96/97 97/98

98/99 99/00

00/01 01/02

02/03 03/04

04/05 05/06

06/07 07/08

08/09 Million Tones

China, Peoples Republic of United States EU Rest of the W orld

Bio-fuels are close substitutes to fossil-fuels as such subjected to specific national market structures. Mandatory blending requirements are common for biodiesel and ethanol, standards of energy efficiency and environment protection must be similar to fossil fuels. Pricing must also be consistent to the regulatory framework applied to fossil fuels, which differs widely between countries. Food security and agricultural price policy are part of an independent set of regulatory framework, both with a strong historical heritage. There is a lot of work to be done in order to make these two sets of regulations consistent within each country, much more so between countries.

As an example from Germany, in July 2007, pump average price of diesel was US$ 1.62 per liter (at current exchange rate); assuming that the highest share for vegetable oil cost is 72% of pump price in order to warrant a good profit for industry and retailer, the highest price to be paid for soybean oil should be US$ 1.27 per kg.

(9)

(0.92 kg of vegetable oil for 1 liter of biodiesel). Soon after the northern hemisphere harvest, CBOT future price for soybean was just above the $1300 level. After March of 2008, when most subsidies where abandoned in Europe, price began to fall dramatically.

3. Food, Energy, Prices and Productive Structure

There is a close relation between the role that food and energy play in the productive structure of the countries and how the countries will react to policies related to fossil-fuel, bio-fuels and food.

To better analyze this relation we have select eight countries with different levels of development and which are important players in the world in terms of food and energy consumption and production. The selected countries are Argentina, Brazil, China, India, United States, France, Germany and Japan.

The basis for the analysis are the comparable Input-Output Matrices released by OECD (see OECD, 2006), and which refers to the year of 2000 for Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany and Japan, the year of 1997 for Argentina, and the year of 1998/99 for India.

Figure 8 shows the shares of total value of imports, food imports, and energy imports in the total value of production of the select countries, while Figure 9 shows the share of food and energy in total imports. From these figures it is possible to see that France and Germany are the more opened economies, with imports representing respectively 14.5% and 17.1% of their total output, while for the other economies the share of imports varies between 5.8% and 8.2%. As for food and energy imports, they represent a small share of the total value o production, between 0.4% and 1.2% for food and between 0.2% and 1.3% for energy. In all the other countries being analyzed, with the exception of Argentina, the share of energy imports are higher than the share of food imports, and in the cases of Brazil, India and USA energy has more than the double of importance of the food imports.

Figure 10 shows the role played by imports of food and energy in total disposable food and energy, while Figure 11 shows the share of imported inputs in the production of coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel. When one gets inside

(10)

the countries it is possible to see that imported energy has a high share in the total disposable energy for the countries being considered than food has, with special importance for France (25.1%), Germany (25.6$), and Japan (18.3%), followed by India (14.0%) and USA (14.2%), an in a lesser scale China (7.2%), Brazil (10.9%) and Argentina (4.8%). However, it is possible to see the high dependence that France, Germany and Japan have on imported inputs for energy production, more than 98%, followed by India (55.4%), USA (50.9%), China (30.6%), Brazil (19.2%), and Argentina (7.7%). As for food consumption the higher dependence on imports is found in Germany (20.9%), France (16.2%), and Japan (10.6%), followed by USA (6.7%), while in the other countries the dependence is less than 4%.

In summary, from the analysis of Figures 8 to 11 it is possible to see that in terms of imports, energy is more important than food and that, with the exception of Brazil and Argentina, there is a high dependence of the other economies on imports of primary energy for secondary energy production.

Figure 8 – Share of Imports in Total Output of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

2.0%

4.0%

6.0%

8.0%

10.0%

12.0%

14.0%

16.0%

18.0%

Argentin a

Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 0.4% 0.4% 0.4% 0.5% 0.3% 1.2% 1.2% 0.8%

Energy 0.2% 1.0% 0.7% 1.3% 0.7% 1.3% 1.3% 1.0%

Total 7.5% 6.7% 7.5% 8.2% 7.5% 14.5% 17.1% 5.8%

Share of Imports in Total Output

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

(11)

Figure 9 – Share of Food and Energy in Total Imports of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

2.0%

4.0%

6.0%

8.0%

10.0%

12.0%

14.0%

16.0%

18.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 5.5% 5.9% 5.8% 6.6% 4.0% 7.9% 7.2% 13.0%

Energy 2.6% 15.0% 8.9% 15.8% 9.8% 9.2% 7.7% 17.7%

Share of Food and Energy in Total Imports

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

Figure 10 – Share of Imported Food and Energy in Total Disposable Food and Energy of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

5.0%

10.0%

15.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 3.9% 2.9% 2.8% 2.2% 6.7% 16.2% 20.9% 10.6%

Energy 4.8% 10.9% 7.2% 14.0% 14.2% 25.1% 25.6% 18.3%

Share of Imported Food and Energy in Total Disposable Food and Energy

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

(12)

Figure 11 – Share of Imported Inputs in the Total Value of Mining and Querying (energy) used in the Sector of Coke, Refined Petroleum Products and Nuclear Fuel of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

10.0%

20.0%

30.0%

40.0%

50.0%

60.0%

70.0%

80.0%

90.0%

100.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Série1 7.7% 19.2% 30.6% 55.4% 50.9% 97.6% 98.5% 99.5%

Share of Imported Inputs in the Total Value o Mining and Querying (energy) used in the Sector of Coke, Refined Petroleum Products and Nuclear Fuel

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

Figures 12 to 14 show the importance of food and energy for production (intermediate consumption), final demand and in the total output of the economy.

For the intermediate consumption, the economies being considered can be divided into two groups, the first one consisting of developing economies - Argentina, Brazil, China, and India – in which the added shares of food and energy into intermediate consumption are between 24% and 32%, and the developed economies – USA, France, Germany, and Japan – which the added share are between 12% and 14%, i.e., less than half of the shares observed for the developing economies. Inside each country, on general the shares observed for food are close to the ones observed for energy, with the exception of Argentina (food, 15.7%, and energy, 8.3%), USA (food, 4.8%, and energy, 7.2%), and Japan (food, 5.8%, and energy, 7.6%).

As for the final demand shares, energy in all of the economies being considered represent less than 3% of the final demand, however, for food, its share goes from 4.1%

in the USA to 28.4% in India. In the developed economies being considered, the share of food is less than 8%, while for the developing economies it has a value of around

(13)

13% for Argentina and Brazil, going to 19.3% in China and 28.4% in India. This structure shows the importance of food in less developed economies, due to the structure of consumption of the low income classes where food has a greater relative importance than the other consumer goods.

Overall, i.e., considering the total output in the economy, as show in Figure 14, the share of energy in total output in the developing economies (around 7.0%) is about double of the one found in developed economies (around 3.5%). As for food, Argentina, Brazil and China have a share of around 15% of the total output, while for India the share is of 25.1% and for the developed economies the share is between 4.4% for the USA and 7.4% for France. This again reinforce the results found above, showing the relative low importance of food and energy for the developed economies, in terms of value of production, when compared to its importance in less developed economies.

Figure 12 – Share of Food and Energy in Intermediate Consumption of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

2.0%

4.0%

6.0%

8.0%

10.0%

12.0%

14.0%

16.0%

18.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 15.7% 15.1% 11.7% 16.8% 4.8% 7.0% 5.0% 5.8%

Energy 8.3% 15.3% 13.1% 15.6% 7.2% 6.3% 5.8% 7.6%

Share of Food and Energy in Intermediate Consumption

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

(14)

Figure 13 – Share of Food and Energy in Final Demand of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

5.0%

10.0%

15.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 13.1% 12.8% 19.3% 28.4% 4.1% 7.7% 5.5% 6.1%

Energy 2.8% 1.8% 1.4% 1.7% 2.2% 2.7% 2.0% 1.9%

Share of Food and Energy in Final Demand

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

Figure 14 – Share of Food and Energy in Total Demand of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

5.0%

10.0%

15.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 14.9% 14.8% 15.8% 25.1% 4.4% 7.4% 5.0% 5.7%

Energy 5.1% 7.4% 8.2% 6.7% 3.9% 3.5% 3.0% 3.6%

Share of Food and Energy in Total Output

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

This directly reflects on the disposable value added generated in the economies being considered here, Figure 15. While for China and India the combined importance of food and energy is respectively of 31.4% and 35.2%, for Brazil is 18.1%, for Argentina is 12.3%, and for the developed economies is less than 10%. With the

(15)

exception of the USA, in all the other countries food has a greater share in the economy than energy.

As can be seen in Figure 16, the relation between food and energy in the generation of the disposable domestic value is 0,73 for the USA, around 1,50 for Brazil, France, Germany, and Japan, around 2,2 for Argentina and China, and of 5,1 for India.

As a consequence of that, one can see that a policy of bio-fuels that would imply a substitution of food for energy, with the exception of the USA, will put more stress over the economies than a policy of price increase of energy and/or a policy of substitution of fossil-fuel energy from other sources than bio-fuels energy.

Figure 15 – Share of Disposable Domestic Value Added of Food and Energy in GDP of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.0%

5.0%

10.0%

15.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Food 8.6% 10.7% 21.4% 29.4% 2.6% 5.2% 3.7% 5.2%

Energy 3.7% 7.4% 10.0% 5.8% 3.6% 3.5% 2.7% 4.2%

Share of Disposable Domestic Value Added in the GDP

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

(16)

Figure 16 – Relation of Disposable Domestic Value Added Between Food and Energy of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

Série1 2.36 1.46 2.14 5.09 0.73 1.49 1.37 1.26

(VA + VAM - VAE) Relation:

Food / Energy

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

The relative importance of food and energy in the economies can also be estimated by measuring the price transmission effects of a price increase in the economy, as displayed in Figures 17 and 18 that show the impact of a 10% increase, respectively, of food and energy over the wholesale price index (WPI) and the consumer price index (CPI). The results show, as expected, that the increase of food price will have a greater impact over the CPI while the increase of energy price will have, with the exception of France and Germany, a greater impact over the WPI. Also, the impact on the CPI due to an increase of food price is greater than the one due to an increase of energy price, in all the countries being considered here. As for the impact of food and energy prices over the WPI, one has that for Argentina and India the impact of food prices are clearly greater than the impact of energy prices, while for the other countries being considered, there are only slight differences between the impact of food and energy prices.

However, it must be stressed that impacts over the developing economies are greater than the ones in the developed ones. For food, while one has at most an impact of 1.56% in the WPI of France, for the developing countries it starts at 1.67% in the WPI of Argentina and goes up through 5.0% in the CPI of China. For an increase in the energy prices, the impact over Brazil, China and India are clearly greater than the one for Argentina, USA, France, Germany, and Japan.

(17)

As a reflect of this, there is enough room for the developed countries being considered here, mainly France, Germany and Japan to practice polices of high prices on the energy with lower impact over the economy, as they are used to do.

Special attention need to be paid to China, due to its size and important role in the world trade. From the above analysis it is clear the importance of cheap food and energy for the development of China and the adverse impacts that an increase in their prices will have over the Chinese economy, internally and in its competitivity in the international market.

Figure 17 – Impact of a 10% Change on the Price of Food on the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) and on the Consumer Price Index of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

WPI 1.67 1.78 2.18 2.83 0.58 0.86 0.62 0.69

CPI 1.79 2.32 5.00 4.84 0.78 1.56 1.27 1.42

Impact of a 10% Change on the Price of Food on the

Wholesale Price Index (WPI) and on the Consumer Price Index (CPI)

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

(18)

Figure 18 – Impact of a 10% Change on the Price of Energy on the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) and on the Consumer Price Index of Selected Developing and Developed Countries

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00

Argentina Brazil China India USA France Germany Japan

WPI 0.86 1.72 2.35 1.50 0.73 0.66 0.65 0.84

CPI 0.57 1.25 1.36 0.93 0.62 0.78 0.73 0.72

Impact of a 10% Change on the Price of Energy on the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) and on the Consumer Price Index (CPI

Note: Argentina refers to 1997; Brazil, China, USA, France, Germany, and Japan to 2000; and India to 1998/99.

Source: Estimated from OECD (2006)

The above also implies that the substitution of fossil-fuel for bio-fuel will be only feasible in countries that have enough land to expand the bio-fuel production without compromising the production of food or putting more stress over the environment. In the Brazilian case, Figures 19 to 21 that display, respectively, the stress over the Brazilian territory of cattle, soybean, and sugar cane production in 1995 and 2006, show that the cattle production is putting a stress over the Amazon forest, and the land left behind, due to its expansion, are being occupied by soybean production. On the other hand, the sugar cane production seems to have its own pattern of growth without putting much stress over the environment, and food production, in the period being considered.

(19)

Figure 19 – Cattle Production Stress over the Brazilian Territory – 1995 and 2006

Legenda

Numero de cabeças 4 - 50,000 50,001 - 150,000 150,001 - 250,000 250,001 - 400,000 400,001 - 600,000 600,001 - 800,000 800,001 - 1,200,000 1,200,001 - 2,000,000

Bovinocultura Ano 1995

Fonte: Adaptado de Pesquisa Pecuária Municipal - IBGE

Visão Tridimensional

Legenda

Numero de cabeças 4 - 50,000 50,001 - 150,000 150,001 - 250,000 250,001 - 400,000 400,001 - 600,000 600,001 - 800,000 800,001 - 1,200,000 1,200,001 - 2,000,000

Bovinocultura Ano 2006

Fonte: Adaptado de Pesquisa Pecuária Municipal - IBGE

Visão Tridimensional

(20)

Figure 20 – Soybean Production Stress over the Brazilian Territory – 1995 and 2006

Soja Ano 1995

Fonte: Adaptado de Pesquisa Agrícola Municipal - IBGE

Visão Tridimensional

Legenda

Quantidade em Toneladas 0 - 30,000 30,001 - 80,000 80,001 - 150,000 150,001 - 250,000 250,001 - 400,000 400,001 - 700,000 700,001 - 1,100,000 1,100,001 - 1,800,000

Soja Ano 2006

Fonte: Adaptado de Pesquisa Agrícola Municipal - IBGE

Visão Tridimensional

Legenda

Quantidade em Toneladas 0 - 30,000 30,001 - 80,000 80,001 - 150,000 150,001 - 250,000 250,001 - 400,000 400,001 - 700,000 700,001 - 1,100,000 1,100,001 - 1,800,000

(21)

Figure 21 – Sugar Cane Production Stress over the Brazilian Territory – 1995 and 2006

Cana de Açúcar Ano 1995

Fonte: Adaptado de Pesquisa Agrícola Municipal - IBGE

Visão Tridimensional

Legenda

Quantidade em Toneladas 0 - 50,000 50,001 - 100,000 100,001 - 250,000 250,001 - 500,000 500,001 - 1,000,000 1,000,001 - 1,800,000 1,800,001 - 3,000,000 3,000,001 - 5,300,000

Cana de Açúcar Ano 2006

Fonte: Adaptado de Pesquisa Agrícola Municipal - IBGE

Visão Tridimensional

Legenda

Quantidade em Toneladas 0 - 50,000 50,001 - 100,000 100,001 - 250,000 250,001 - 500,000 500,001 - 1,000,000 1,000,001 - 1,800,000 1,800,001 - 3,000,000 3,000,001 - 5,300,000

(22)

4. Concluding Remark

The above analysis has show that in general food puts a greater stress over the economies than energy does, and mainly in the developing economies. As a consequence of that, the possibilities for the growing use of bio-fuels is limited and restrict to countries where it is possible to have an expansion of bio-fuel production without compromising the production of food and without putting more stress over the environment. This, by its turn, restricts the possibilities for a world policy of bio-fuels with the consequence that bilateral agreements would be the dominant ones. As so, an implication for a world policy would be to start the process of negotiation with bilateral agreements, than slowly evolving into regional trade, as it is a more realistic framework for a safe development of bio-fuels markets.

5. References

German Biomass Sustainability Ordinance- commentary paper to the draft, Institute for Energy and Environment, Leipzig, January 2008.

OECD (2006). The OECD Input-Output Database as presented by Norihiko Yamano and Nadim Ahmad (2006), “The OECD Input-Output Database: 2006 Edition”. STI Working Paper 2006/8. Statistical Analysis of Science, Technology and Industry.

Wolf, Martin (2008). Food crisis is a chance to reform global agriculture, FT-April 29, 2008.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

If subsidies were actually to be reduced and a price for CO2 emissions agreed, the capital tied into fossil energy sources would be devalued, however, as it is currently the

The DART-BIO model includes 3 different types of DDGS and 4 different types of meals/cakes as by-products of biofuel production: DDGS from maize, wheat and other grains,

In this paper we use new time-series data on the Canadian underground economy compiled by Giles and Tedds (2002) to examine the causal relationship between the underground and

(1) it affects the amount of carbon that is fixed in wood products (product storage), and (2) it substitutes materials that require more fossil energy in their

Cultures co-expressing HbpD-SpT2, HbpD-SpT2-LL or HbpD-SpT2-LL with BAM were incubated with SpC2-mScarlet or not to allow for coupling of the fluorescent protein to the

Another finding regarding the Indian new middle class from this manuscript is that despite the class-distinctive aspects of their food practices, they also try to overcome

We give an example of a pure group that does not have the independence property, whose Fitting subgroup is neither nilpotent nor definable and whose soluble radical is neither

in vehicle fuel systems, separates from gasoline under water con- tamination, and can cause vapor lock (an interruption in the fuel flow). Cold weather starting is made more of