• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Urban Highways and the Demise of Private Mass Transit in the United States

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Urban Highways and the Demise of Private Mass Transit in the United States"

Copied!
22
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

NOT FOR QUOTATION WITHOUT PERMISSION OF THE AUTHOR

URBAN

HIGHWAYS AND THE DEMISE

OF PRZYATE

M A S TRANSIT

IN

THE UNITED

SIXITS

Stephen P. Dresch

November 1983 WP-83-120

Working Papers are interim reports on work of the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and have received only limited review. Views or opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of the Institute or of its National Member Organizations.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS

ANALYSIS

236 1 Laxenburg, Austria

(2)

Public policies exert critical influences on t h e structure and composi- tion of economic activity. This paper i s the first of a series planned by the author on the general subject of "constitutionalism and incremen- talism" in predominantly market economies. Focusing on the progres- sive displacement of mass transit by the private auto in local transporta- tion and on t h e concomitant conversion of mass transit t o a primarilly public-sector activity, t h e paper provides a concrete setting for the con- ceptual and analytical studies which will follow.

Anatoli Smyshlyaev Program Leader (Acting)

Patterns of Economic Structural Change and Industrial Adjustment International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis

Laxenburg. Austria

(3)

STEPHEN P. DRESCH is a research scholar a t t h e International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and chairman of the Institute for Demo- graphic and Economic Studies, New Haven, Connecticut.

(4)

PREFACE

In a "popular" critique of t h e Reagan Administration's proposed (and now enacted) "transportation infrastructure investment" program ("Save t h e Infrastructure

-

By Auctioning It Off," Opinion and Commentary, ?he

Christian Science Monitor, December 9, 1982, reproduced as an attach- m e n t t o this paper), I suggested the likelihood of inefficiencies and unanticipated consequences associated with such governmental initia- tives in predominantly market or mixed economies, proposing as a exam- ple of the l a t t e r t h e apparent consequences of highway expansion for governmental involvement in mass transportation. Subsequently, in thinking about the implications of incrementalist political processes, t h i s case s t r u c k me a s an excellent example of t h e invasive aspect of unconstrained incrementalism and as one which was susceptible t o con- c r e t e empirical analysis. The product is t h e present paper, which offers empirical support for a principle conjecture of t h e earlier commentary (cited above) a n d a specific case study for the more general analysis of

"constitutionalism and political incrementalism."

The paper h a s benefited from discussions with a number of IlASA a n d nonIZPLSA colleagues. In particular, Wolfgang Schiipp of IIASA and t h e Technical University of Vienna collaborated in the statistical analysis a n d designed t h e generalized least squares model reported in the Appen- dix. The author alone, of course, bears ultimate responsibility for the analysis a n d i t s interpretation.

Stephen

P.

Dresch Laxenburg, Austria

(5)

URBAN HIGHWAYS AND

THE DE%ISE OF

PRlYATE MASS TRANSIT

IN THE

UNITED STATES

Stephen P. Dresch

Virtually any action by any party in any sphere has a large number of consequences, of greater or lesser importance, for other parties. While many of these consequences a r e consciously intended, many, perhaps most, a r e unintentional. Whether intentional or unintentional, t h e effi- ciency of the system within which t h e consequences of an action a r e exerted ultimately depends upon t h e existence of mechansims which insure t h a t parties a r e encouraged to take actions the n e t consequences of which a r e positive a n d a r e constrained from taking actions which involve negative n e t consequences.

Markets constitute a n important mechanism employed by one class of societies t o a t t e m p t t o m e e t this condition in t h e economic sphere.

The principle issue underlying t h i s paper concerns t h e efficiency impli-

(6)

cations of governmental action within one subset of this class of economies, t h a t subset characterized by pluralistic political systems.

Thus, t h e paper is concerned not with t h e relative efficiencies of m a r k e t versus p l a n n e d economies but r a t h e r with t h e efficiency with which governmental and nongovernmental actions a r e integrated in the former. The c e n t r a l , if a t t h i s stage implicit, elements of t h e argument can be briefly indicated:

(1) Governmental actions a r e not subject t o t h e types of m a r k e t t e s t s t o which private actions a r e subject. Hence an important source of the feedback by which inefficient actions a r e discouraged or negated (notably bankruptcy) is lost.

(2) In a decentralized, pluralistic political system the adverse conse- quences of any action, not t h e underlying, precipitating action itself, provide t h e focus of governmental response. As a result, actions with adverse consequences (gross o r net) almost inevitably l e a d t o f u r t h e r actions in other spheres, r a t h e r t h a n t o reassess- m e n t s of t h e efficiency implications of t h e precipitating prior actions.

(3) Therefore, politically pluralistic societies with market economies contain an internal bias toward t h e invasive extension of t h e govern- m e n t a l sphere of activity.

This paper does n o t purport to offer proof of these conjectures. Instead, it s e t s t h e stage for a m o r e fundamental analysis by examining t h e consequences of one class of governmental actions for a component of t h e private sector of t h e economy and for subsequent governmental

(7)

actions.

2. The Postwar Demise of Private Mass Transit

Prior to and in the years immediately followring World War 11, mass transit in the United States was a primarily private activity. Thus, of the 1,406 operating transit systems in 1950. only 26 systems (1.8 percent of the total) were publically owned. While the public systems were larger than average, they nonetheless accounted for only 28 percent of all transit vehicles. As indicated by Table 1, however, this situation changed dramatically over the following 30 years. By 1980 the number of operat- ing systems had declined by 25 percent (to 1,044), whike the number of publically-owned systems increased by 2,216 percent (to 576), compris- ing in excess of 55 percent of all systems. Concomitantly, the publically-owned proportion of all transit vehicles increased from 28 per- cent t o 90 percent. In short, over a period of 30 years an essentially private mass transit system was effectively absorbed by the public sec- tor. The present paper briefly explores the sources of this rapid demise of private mass transit in the United States.

A perusal of t h e passenger-load and financial statistics included in Table 1 provides a relatively clear indication of the immediate causes of the demise of the privately-owned component of the mass transit system.

Despite rapid increases in population and economic activity, e.g., employment, transit ridership declined by 34 percent between 1950 and 1955, by 18 percent between 1955 and 1960, by 10 percent between 1960 and 1965, by 13 percent between 1965 and 1970 and by five percent between 1970 and 1975, for a cumulative decline of almost 60 percent

(8)

over this 25 year period. Financially. in 1950 operating expenditure exclusive of taxes was equal to only 89 percent of operating revenue, a figure which rose t o 92 percent in 1960, to 111 percent in 1970 and to 177 percent in 1975. Net operating income (equal t o operating revenue less operating expenses inclusive of taxes) declined from $66 million in 1950 t o $31 million in 1960, $-I1 million in 1965, $-288 million in 1970, $-1.704 million in 1975, and, finally, $-3,818 million in 1980; as a percentage of operating revenue t h e decline was from 4.5 p e r c e n t i n 1950 to -141.6 per- c e n t in 1980. Not suprisingly, public operating assistance by 1980 had reached $3,618 million. equal to 134 percent of operating revenue and to 56 percent of operating expenditure (inclusive of taxes). In short, mass transit (public and private) moved from moderate profitability in 1950 to a breakeven s t a t e in t h e mid 1960s to losses well in excess of operating revenues (passenger fares primarily) in 1980.

At a superficial level, t h e decline in passenger ridership provides a plausible explanation for t h e deterioration in t h e financial s t a t u s of t h e mass t r a n s i t industry. while t h e financial collapse of t h e industry pro- vides a

similar!^

plausible explanation for t h e progressive incorporation of the industry i n t o t h e public sector. The unanswered question, how- ever, i s precisely why t r a n s i t ridership declined a s i t did. If this contrac- tion was simply a m a t t e r of a shift in consumer preferences away from mass t r a n s i t or of t h e effects of rising affluence on t h e s t r u c t u r e of tran- sportation demands, t h e n t h e r e would be n e i t h e r a significant cause for concern n o r a legitimate "second-best" justification for t h e public- sector "rescue" of t h e mass transit industry. If, however, this veritable collapse of transit demand c a n be traced n o t t o t h e independent actions

(9)

-

Table 1

~ r a h s i t and Highway Statistics, 1950-1980

1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980

T W S I T

v. pass. (mil.) 13,845 9,189 7,521 6,798 5,932 5,643 6,358(P)

on pub. systems

NA N A N A N A

77% 90% 94%(P)

bper. rev. (mil. $) 1,452 1.426 1.407 1,444 1.707 2,002 2,696(P)

IOp.

exp. (mil. $) 1,386 1,370 1,377 1,454 1,996 3.753 6,514(P)

e t op.inc. (mil. $) 66 56 3 1 -1 1 -288 -1,704 -3.818(P) assist. (mil. $)

NA N A N A N A N A

1,408 3,618(P) p. systems (no.) 1,406 1,483 1,251 1,148 1,079 947 1,044

Pub. owned (no.) 26 33 54 78 144 333 576

Pub. % of total

P

ehicles owned (no.) 24,570 22,011 23,738 29,592 1.8% 2.2% 4.3% 6.8% 40,778 13.3% 51,964 64,128 35.2% 55.2%

% pub. owned

I

28% 30% 36% 48% 66% 83% 90%

ontract awards (m.$) 1.528 2,619 4,039 4,825 6,506 -7.187 9,865 funds (mil. $) 415 867 2,292 3,001 3,657 4,824 6,427 27.2% 25.5% 56.7% 62.2% 56.2% 67.1% 65.0%

ed. aided hiways

compl. in yr. 20,000 23,000 28,830 18.783 10,935 7,161

N A

Cost (mil. $) 753 1,287 3,652 ' 4,563 4,353 4.218

NA

Fed. fin. (%) 51.8% 51.7% 68.6% 74.3% 75.0% 76.1%

N A

iles under const.

NA N A

25,538 25,883 20,831 15,952

NA

Cost (mil. $)

NA N A

7,080 12,228 14,547 20,104

NA

Fed. fin. (5%)

P N A N A

73.2% 78.4% 77.4% 79.3% 80.8%

Sources: I l f m d met Book (1981). Washington, D.C.: American Publir Transit Association, 1982.

Satistical Abstract of the Vnited S a t e s (1969, 1972. 1875 1980, 198383). Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Off-ic~

(various years).

Note:

N A

denotes not available, (P) denotes preliminary.

(10)

of "sovereign" consumers but t o t h e inducements of public policy, t h e n the legitimacy of the underlying, causative policy can be questioned, while t h e justifiability of public sector action in defense of m a s s transit would be a t least partially demonstrated.

3. Urban

Highway Expansion a n d the Decline of Transit Ridership

The thesis developed here is t h a t t h e primary explanation for t h e precip- itous decline in mass t r a n s i t demand in the post-war period i s the rapid expansion of urban highway systems. While o t h e r public policies, notably regulations of t h e financial system which resulted in artifically low interest r a t e s on home mortgages and provisions of the Federal (and sub- sequently s t a t e ) income tax which discriminated in favor of single-family home ownership (especially in socially and economically homogeneous suburban areas), contributed to a n d reinforced t h e effects of a rapidly expanding urban highway network, t h e consequences of expansion of t h e highway system a r e most easily and clearly demonstrated.

Between 1963 and 1977 ( t h e only period over which consistent data a r e available), total

U.S.

milage of "municipal highways" (highways in urban areas) increased from 475,000 to 687,000, a 45 percent increase of wbich t h e mandated local components of the Federal i n t e r s t a t e highway system and related roadways constituted a small but not insignificant fraction. Over t h e first nine years of this period, m a s s t r a n s i t ridership declined from 6,915 million t o 5,253 million, o r by 24 percent, before recovering (marginally) t o 5,723 million in 1977. To what e x t e n t can t h e decline in transit ridership be attributed t o t h e expansion of t h e urban highway system?

(11)

To provide a t least a tentative (and, in fact, an arguably definitive) answer to this question, a very simple single-equation model of transit demand is proposed, a model which, despite its simplicity, is quite defen- sible.' Because journeys to work account for a significant fraction of all mass transit trips. t h e dependent variable in this model is defined as the ratio of total revenue passenger transit trips to total employment (full- and part-time). The explanatory variables are:

(1) milage of municipal highways (thousands);

(2) t h e implicit price deflator of user-operated (primarily auto) tran- sportation relative t o the implicit personal consumption expendi- t u r e (PCE) deflator (with 1972

=

1.00 for all variables);

(3) t h e mean transit fare relative to t h e implicit PCE deflator (i.e., expressed in constant 1972 dollars); and

(4) t h e ratio of population to emploqrnent.

Estimating this equation in t h e natureal logarithms of all variables, the coefficients represent elasticities, i.e., percentage changes in t h e depen- dent variable implied by one percent changes in the explanatory vari- ables.

This single-equation model was estimated utilizing annual observa- tions for t h e United States over t h e period 1963 through 1977, with t h e following results:

*Because the explanatory variables in this model can be viewed as determined independent- ly of transit ridership (the dependent variable), the estimated coefficients of the model will not suiier from simultaneou*equations biaa. The independence of the explanatory variables h m the dependent variable is unarguable in the case of the urban-highway-milage, user operated-transportation-price-relative and population-employment-ratio variables. More over, at least over the estimation period, this independence appears to be generally true as well with reference to the relative price of public transit, determined largely by "ex*

genous" political decisions of the various levels of government subsidizing mass transit.

(12)

-

1.21 ln(municipa1 highway milage) (0.07)

[-17.031

+

0.36 ln(re1. user-op. trans. deflator) (0.10)

[3.49]

-

0.85 ln(re1ative transit price) (0.07)

[-I 1.501

~2

=

0.997

S a n d a r d e r r o r o f r e g r e s s i o n

=

0.013 F - s t a t i s t i c (4, 10)

=

753.49 Durbin -Watson s t a t i s t i c

=

2.72

( ) Std. error of est. coefficient.

[...I:

Coefficient t-statistic.

Interpretively, a one-percent increase in miles of urban highways implies a 1.2 percent decline in revenue passengers of local transit sys- tems. With reference t o prices, a one-percent increase in t h e relative price of user-operated transportation induces an 0.36 percent increase in transit passengers, while a one-percent increase in relative transit fares results in an 0.85 percent decline in transit ridership. Finally, a one-percent increase in t h e ratio of population t o employment implies an 0.46 percent increase in transit ridership, suggesting t h a t t h e aver- age nonemployed person uses approximately one-fourth t h e transit

(13)

s e r v i c e s of a n e m p l o y e d p e r s o n w h e n t h e r a t i o of p o p u l a t i o n t o e m p l o y - men t i s a p p r o x i m a t e l y 2.5.

*

*A number of reviewers of an earlier version of this paper suggested the possibility that municipal highway milage, which increases monotonically over the perjod and which, almost definitionally, does not decline, might simply be capturing a downward time trend in transit riderahip. To test this possibility, a second version of the basic transit ridership equation was estimated, explicitly includmg an exponential time trend (1863 = I ) , with the following results:

-

0.008 (year

-

1962)

(o.ooe) [-1.1121

-

0.80 ln(municipal highway milage) ( 0 . m

[-3.171

+

0.33 ln(re1. user-02. trans. deflator) (0.10)

(3.161

-

0.88 ln(re1ative transit price) (0.W

[-11.01]

~2 = 0.887

Standard error of regression = 0.013 F-statistic ( 5 , 9) = 617.86 h r b i n -Watson statistic = 2.66

Aa c a n be observed, inclusion of the time trend does reduce the absolute value of the elesti- city of transit ridership with respect to municipal highway milage, but the change is only from -1.2 t o -0.9, and elasticities with respect to the relative price of user-operated tran- sportation and the population-employment ratio are also reduced. Perhaps most important- ly, the time trend itself is not statistically significant, with a coefficient only marginally greater than i t s standard error (while a coefficient approximately twice the standard error would be necessllrg for mgnificance a t the five percent level). A s the coefficient of determi- nation and the standard error of the regression indicate, the addition of the time trend does not appreciably improve the fit of the equation t o the data. LTI short, there seems t o be n o reeson either t o believe t h a t the hghway milage variable is simply a proxy for a more gen- eral temporal process of modal shift (from mess transit to the private auto) or t o substitute the equation incluhng the time trend for the more parsimonious equation presented in the text.

(14)

Table 2 indicates q u i t e graphically t h e degree t o which this e s t i m a t e d equation a c c o u n t s for t h e reality of t h e period. The first column p r e s e n t s predicted values of t h e r a t i o of t r a n s i t passengers t o employment, t h e second t h e actually observed values. Both predicted a n d observed values decline monotonically from 1963 t o 1973, t h e predicted values from 107 t o 63, t h e observed values from 106 t o 63.

Predicted a n d observed values t h e n rise t o 65 in 1974 a n d t o 67 in 1975, a f t e r which declines a r e again observed in 1976 and 1977, with predicted values of 66 a n d 63 v e r s u s observed values of 65 a n d 64.

Table 2

Transit Ridership, Actual and Predicted, a n d Its D e t e r m i n a n t s

e a r Predicted Actual Municipal Rel. User- RevPass/Emp RevPass/Emp Highway Op. Trans.

Ratio Ratio Miles Deflator

Relative Population- Transit Employment

Fare Ratio

.26873 2.8905 .27066 2.8592 -27515 2.7946 .27923 2.6801 .28893 2.6396 .28463 2.5925 .29150 2.5441 .31109 2.5769 .32821 2.6160 .329 15 2.5805 .32131 2.5026 .29730 2.4863 .283 14 2.5585 -28924 2.5154 .28600 2.4572

Note: Municipal highway miles a r e expressed in thousands.

Thus, notwithstanding i t s simplicity t h e model c o r r e c t l y predicts t h e 1973-74 a n d 1975-76 t u r n i n g points. Interestingly, however, t h e rea- s o n s for t h e t u r n i n g points a r e n o t quite what one m i g h t expect, a s indi- c a t e d by t h e values of t h e explanatory variables a s presented in t h e t h i r d

(15)

through sixth columns of Table 2. Clearly. t h e rise from 1973 to 1974 was due primarily to t h e seven percent decline in t h e relative t r a n s i t fare, reinforced by t h e comparatively slight 7,000 mile increase in urban high- ways. Contrary t o popular perceptions (and despite an increase in gaso- line prices), the relative price of user-operated transportation actually declined by four percent between 1973 a n d 1974, while t h e ratio of popu- lation t o employment was virtually unchanged.

Equally clearly, t h e resumption of declining transit ridership after 1975 was due to t h e resurgence of growth in urban highway milage, with 9,000 miles added in 1976 and 39,000 miles added in 1977, t h e effects of which were only partially offset by t h e rising relative price of user- operated transportation. Transit fares remained relatively constant a f t e r 1975, while t h e population-employment ratio declined modestly, reinforcing the depressive effects of highway expansion.

To place in bold relief t h e impact of post-1963 highway construction,

if

u r b a n highway milage had remained constant while all o t h e r explana- tory variables took actually observed values, t h e estimated equation predicts t h a t t h e r e would have been 99 t r a n s i t rides per employed person in 1977, only six p e r c e n t fewer t h a n in 1963. In reality, t r a n s i t ridership relative t o employment declined t o 64, o r by 40 percent from its 1963 level of 106. Thus, of t h e observed decline, 8 5 percent can be attributed t o expansion of t h e urban highway system, only 15 percent t o increased t r a n s i t fares and other factors.

(16)

4. Conclusion

In summary, t h e expansion of t h e urban highway system (largely a t Federal expense, as will be indicated) induced a serious erosion in t r a n s i t ridership, t h e consequence of which was t h e financial demise of t h e private mass-transportation sector in the United States. A s a result, mass t r a n s i t h a s been effectively absorbed by t h e public sector, requir- ing large and growing operating subsidies (not t o mention subsidies for capital investment, with direct Federal capital subsidies alone increasing f r o m $51 million in 1965 to $2.8 billion in 1980).

If t h e underlying expansion of t h e urban highway system and decline in t r a n s i t ridership simply reflected t h e free play of m a r k e t forces, t h e n t h e foregoing would constitute little more t h a n an exercise (hopefully interesting) in economic analysis. Its only practical import would be t o call into question t h e justification for t h e growing relative subsidization of mass transit. However, t h e modal shift from mass t r a n - s i t t o t h e automobile c a n hardly be viewed a s t h e result of free choices of sovereign consumers in reponse t o unbiased opportunities provided by a f r e e market. With t h e passing of t h e private turnpikes of t h e 18th a n d 19th centuries, highway-system development became an entirely public activity, and, a s Table 1 indicates, t h i s is a n activity expenditure on which has increased dramatically in t h e postwar period. Thus, t h e value of construction contracts (in nominal dollars) increased from $1.5 billion in 1950 t o $9.9 billion in 1980, with t h e Federally-financed s h a r e rising from 27 p e r c e n t t o 6 5 percent.

(17)

In this regard, i t is frequently argued by t h e "highway lobby" t h a t highway "users' fees" more than cover the costs of t h e highway system, and hence t h a t highway users collectively a r e paying a t least t h e

"market" price of highway services. While i t is beyond t h e scope of this paper to definitively refute this claim, a n u m b e r of flaws in t h e a r g u m e n t a r e apparent. First, even if t r u e in the aggregate, it would not be t r u e of individual components of t h e highway system. Thus, relative t o t h e costs of highway rights-of-way, construction and maintenance, c e r t a i n highway users (urban a n d r u r a l ) pay substantially less t h a n others and also sub- stantially less t h a n t h e t r u e economic costs of providing highway ser- vices. Second, t h e nominal costs of highway rights-of-way, construction and maintenance generally significantly understate t h e t r u e economic costs: The power of e m i n e n t domain reduces initial property-acquisition costs, governmental authorities a r e exempt from property and income taxes, highways a r e financed in many cases using tax-exempt borrowing, the expenses of r e p a i r a n d replacement t o be incurred in t h e f u t u r e a r e rarely recognized a s a cost of c u r r e n t highway use, ad nauseum. Finally, third, much of t h e r e v e n u e collected as ostensible highway users' fees is indistinguishable i n economic t e r m s from t h e revenues of taxes levied on o t h e r activities, e.g.. retail sales taxes; only t o t h e degree t o which tax r a t e s on highway-related activities exceed those on o t h e r comparable activities c a n t h e s e t a x e s be viewed as even roughly comparable t o a ser- vice price, in t h i s case a price charged for highway services. In short, in general a n d especially with reference t o urban highways. substantial subsidies a r e involved.

(18)

At t h i s point Federal highnlay funds (including those appropriated as p a r t of t h e Reagan Administration's putative program of bridge and high- way "repairH) a r e t a r g e t e d primarily on completion of the still incom- plete components of t h e i n t e r s t a t e system, and these a r e primarily in urban regions where t h e adverse impact of highway construction on t h e demand for mass t r a n s i t is greatest. Thus, we confront t h e anomolous prospect of incurring extremely high costs for continuing highway build- ing in urban areas and as a result also incurring exponentially increas- ing costs of mass t r a n s i t subsidies a s new highways f u r t h e r erode t r a n s i t demand.

In a r e c e n t column critically reviewing t h e now-enacted Federal gasoline tax increase a n d transportation "infrastructure investment pro- gram" ("Save t h e Infrastructure

--

By Auctioning

I t

Off," Opinion a n d Commentary, 7h.e Christian Science Monitor, December 9, 1982), t h e p r e s e n t author briefly summarized t h e consequences of highway development discussed in t h i s paper:

In major metropolitan a r e a s t h e economically inefficient local components of t h e i n t e r s t a t e system induced an acceleration i n t h e shift from mass t r a n s i t (public a n d private) to t h e private automobile, creating t h e difficulties of t h e t r a n s i t systems (now largely public) which a r e t o be the "beneficiaries" of one-fifth of t h e proposed gasoline-tax-cum-user's fee (while they a r e likely t o be f u r t h e r victimized by t h e four-fifths t o be allocated t o highways)

.

The serious (and, for private companies, fatal) blow t o mass t r a n s i t in t h e 1950s and 1960s was not t h e failure of t h e Federal government t o subsidize transit b u t r a t h e r i t s insistence on subsidizing highways a n d use of t h e private automobile. And just as in 1950, t r a n s i t systems today would benefit more from f o u r dollars n o t d e v o t e d to urban highway

subsidies t h a n from one dollar allocated t o t r a n s i t subsidies.

(19)

% B e L Z

g!; 14

~ $

$4

6

- h a . i

2;. ~ ~ a l ;

'f I??;$

i . 1' e

lii r 3 3

-, 5- Ex

5. El-

,PI ; ' P

"gg,ga

imrl i!

(20)

APPENDIX

An examination of t h e residuals (actual m i n u s predicted values) of t h e estimated t r a n s i t ridership equation presented in t h e t e x t (excluding t h e exponential t i m e t r e n d ) revealed one striking peculiarity: The variance of t h e residuals was markedly higher over t h e ten years prior t o 1973 than in t h e l a s t five years of t h e estimation period.' Thus, while t h e mean residual was very low in both periods (0.0001 for 1963 t o 1972, -0.0002 for 1973 t o 1977), t h e mean a b s o l u t e residua1 (0.0101 for 1963 t o 1972, 0.0052 for 1973 t o 1977) was one-half a s g r e a t in t h e second period.

While a systematic change in t h e variance of t h e e r r o r t e r m of t h e equa- tion would not r e s u l t in biased ordinary-least-squares (OLS) e s t i m a t e s of t h e coefficients, t h e s e e s t i m a t e s would be inefficient.

'While this analysis is restricted t o the equation excluding the time trend, the markedly lmer variance of the residuals in the 1973-77 period was also exhibited by the equation in- cluding the exponential time trend.

(21)

To obtain efficient coefficient estimates, maximum likelihood esti- mates were obtained using interative generalized-least-squares, con- straining all coefficients t o equality in both periods but permitting the variance of t h e e r r o r to differ between t h e two periods, with the following results:

-

1.27 ln(municipa1 highway milage) (0.05)

[-27.71

+

0.39 ln(re1. user-op. trans. deflator) (0.03)

[12.2]

-

0.87 ln(re1ative transit price) (0.03)

1-25.11

Although only t h e coefficient of the population-employment ratio is affected significantly [declining from 0.46 (OLS) t o 0.3 (GLS)], t h e overall improvement in t h e equation is indicated by t h e increase in the log of the likelihood function [from 47.3 (OLS) to 113.7 (GLS)] and by the increased levels of significance of t h e individual coefficients.

I t i s notable t h a t t h e breaking point appears t o occur between 1972 and 1973, with the first oil shock occuring in late 1973. However, why the variance of t h e equation should be affected, by t h e oil embargo or by any other specific development, leaving all coefficients "unchanged," is unclear. Also, in t h e absence of additional data, permitting a longer esti-

(22)

mation period, we cannot be confident t h a t o t h e r c h a r a c t e r i s t i c s of t h e equation did n o t change after 1972. Nonetheless, t h e finding of t h i s sub- s t a n t i a l reduction in t h e purely s t o c h a s t i c c o m p o n e n t of t r a n s i t rider- s h i p is interestingly puzzeling.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

74 The prudent use of American military power, in concert with the economic, political, and diplomatic instruments of national power, remains central to attempts to shape

However, connecting the dots was assigned to another new creation, the Terrorist Threat Integration Center (TTIC), which became the National Counterterrorism Center (NCTC) under

Another pressing research topic is the (non) use of library portals and what kind of improvements are necessary in order to ensure that people will use them for serious

Each position, starting from the second one, contains the storage drive, processing module and devices for parts movement between the positions (fig. We suppose that technological

A major flaw of the Act is that it dealt only with individual household cases and not with the macro economic impact of a mortgage lending boom supported by banking practices often

Anche i paesi mediterranei delle sponde meridionale e orientale, pur rimanendo paesi di origine d’importanti flussi migratori, risultavano caratterizzati da una

Particularly, if the construction of the bus rapid transit (BRT) infrastructure impacted the price market (per square meter or asking price) of the residential and

The variables for equity ratio, months of spending, markup, and liquidity were not shown to have a clear and significant impact on survival time in nonprofits..