• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

ISSN Nr. 0722 - 6748

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "ISSN Nr. 0722 - 6748"

Copied!
14
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

FS IV 94 - 19

Innovation Announcement with Vertical Differentiation

Jim Y. Jin

December 1994

ISSN Nr. 0722 - 6748

discussion papers

Forschungsschwerpunkt Marktprozeß und Unter­

nehmensentwicklung (IIMV) Research Unit

Market Processes and

Corporate Development (IIM)

(2)

Jim Y. Jin, Innovation Announcement with Vertical Differentiation, Discussion Paper FS IV 94-19, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, 1994.

Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung gGmbH, Reichpietschufer 50, 10785 Berlin, Tel. (030) 2 54 91 - 0

(3)

ABSTRACT

Innovation Announcement with Vertical Differentiation*

The paper studies the timing of innovation announcement in a vertical differentiated industry.

The high quality firm introduces new products when they become profitable. The new products can be announced early or late. Under an early announcement policy the low quality firm knows the outcome of innovation when choosing its own quality. Under a late announcement policy, however, the low quality firm can only choose its quality based on the distribution of innovation outcomes. The quality decisions are followed by price competition.

It is shown that an early announcement policy is socially desirable but incompatible with the interest of the innovative firm.

ZUSAMMENFASSUNG

Innovationsankündigung bei vertikaler Differenzierung

In diesem Beitrag wird das Timing von Innovationsankündigungen für eine vertikal differenzierten Industrie untersucht. Das Unternehmen mit einer Hochqualitäts- Produktstrategie führt neue Produkte ein, wenn sie profitabel sind. Neue Produkte können früh oder spät angekündigt werden. Bei einer Politik der frühen Ankündigung kennt das Unternehmen mit der Strategie geringer Produktqualität das Innovationsergebnis, wenn es über seine eigene Produktqualität entscheidet. Bei einer Politik der späten Ankündigung kann sich das Unternehmen mit der Strategie geringer Produktqualität bei seiner Qualitätsentscheidung nur auf die Verteilung der Innovationsergebnisse stützen. A uf die Qualitätsentscheidungen folgt der Preis Wettbewerb. Es wird gezeigt, daß die Politik der frühen Ankündigung sozial erwünscht ist, aber inkompatibel mit dem Interesse des innovativen Unternehmens ist.

* The author would like to thank Dan Kovenock, John Weinberg, Yukiko Hirao, Murgie Krishnan and especially B ill Novshek for their comments and suggestions.

(4)

1. Introduction

The paper studies the timing of innovation announcement in a vertically differentiated industry. The high quality firm improves its product quality. An early announcement allows the low quality firm to upgrade its quality according to the outcome of the high quality firm's innovation. If the innovative firm delays the announcement, however the low quality firm can only adjust its quality based on its expectations. It is shown that a late announcement policy increases the innovative firm's expected profit, but decreases the expected consumers surplus and social welfare. Hence the early announcement policy is socially desirable but not self-enforcing.

In the contemporary economy firms constantly raise product qualities. The pace of quality improvement is often random even if the R&D expenditure is fixed. New products need to be introduced into the market. Empirical studies have shown that product innovation announcement generally increases firms' stock values (Chaney, Devinney and Winer 1991). As marketing is concerned, early announcement gives the product more access to consumers and increases its demand. Nevertheless, not all firms announce new products as soon as they can. Among other considerations, a usual concern is competition from rivals (Eliashberg and Robertson 1988). Given this conflict, innovative firms may announce new products early or late.

In this paper we consider the cases where a firm commits to an early or a late announcement policy in a quality-price game. An early announcement policy allows the rival to adjust its quality with the knowledge of the outcome of innovation. A late announcement policy, however, only allows the low quality firm to know the innovative firm's quality before price setting, but not before quality setting. The commitment to an announcement policy could be enforced by the market, instead of an institution such as a trade association. For instance, under late announcement more intensive market promotion is needed. It requires a marketing strategy different

(5)

2

from one under early announcement. Changing marketing strategies is costly. An irregular announcement policy also causes unnecessary speculation in the stock market and makes a firm's stock riskier. Thus, a firm should have an incentive to stick to a consistent announcement policy. The innovative firm either announces its innovation early or late. The timing of the announcement chosen by the innovative firm may not be in the best interest of consumers and the society. There can be a policy concern whether to encourage or discourage early announcement of product innovation.

The problem of committed announcement comes close to the information sharing literature (Novshek and Sonnenschein 1982, Vives 1984, Gal-Or 1985 and 1986, Li 1985, Sakai 1985). In these models firms commit to information sharing through a trade association. It has been shown that firms with substitute products have incentives to reveal common or private demand uncertainty before price competition, but no incentive to reveal private cost uncertainty. Information sharing before quality setting has not been studied. The previous results have little to say. It is not clear whether innovation uncertainty should be characterized as demand or cost uncertainty, and common or private uncertainty. Directly it only affects one firm's cost function, as we will see, but indirectly it affects both firms' demand. One crucial factor determining information sharing incentives in the previous models is whether firms' reaction curves are downward or upward sloping. It does not apply to our case.

In fact the low quality firm's reaction curve is upward sloping but the high quality firm's reaction curve is flat. These features make information exchange before quality decisions an interesting question.

The next section introduces the model. Section 3 solves the quality-price game.

Section 4 evaluates the impact of early and late announcement policies on profits.

Section 5 examines the welfare effect. The last section concludes the paper.

(6)

2. The Model

NJq consider a two stage quality-price game in a vertically differentiated industry.

Before the game starts, the innovative firm commits to an early announcement policy or a late announcement policy. In the first stage the product innovation is realized and announced if so decided at the beginning. Then firms choose qualities. In the second stage firms set prices knowing qualities. We will evaluate firms' expected profits and the social welfare under early and late announcement policies to see which policy will be chosen and whether it is socially optimal.

Our vertical differentiation model follows Gabszewicz and Thisse (1979), Shaked and Sutton (1982), particularly Tirole (1989). There are two firms. Firm 1 produces the high quality product and firm 2 produces the low quality product. Let Vj be firm i's quality and p; be its price, we have vx > v2. Infinite number of consumers are indexed by 9, which is evenly distributed within [0,1]. Consumer 0 gains surplus 0Vj - pi when he purchases a product from firm i. A higher value of 0 represents a higher preference on the quality. Each consumer purchases at most one product. No purchase occurs if the surplus is negative.

Firms' marginal costs are constant in quantities but increasing in qualities. When firms choose qualities, the marginal costs are also determined. Firm l's marginal cost Ci(vO = avj (a < 1) for vx v and Ci(vx) > vx for Vj > v. Without innovation R&D, v keeps its initial value v°. With R&D the value of v stochastically increases. The value of v is realized before firms choose qualities. A higher v enables firm 1 to produce a higher quality product with a marginal cost avp We need not specify the distribution of v, only assume that it is a common knowledge. Firm 2 can copy firm l's technology from the existing products by reversed engineering. When it chooses its quality, it has the same cost function as firm 1 does up to v°. Thus, its cost function can be written as c2(v2) = av 2 for v2 <. v° and c2(v2) > v2 for v2 > v°.

(7)

4

In the quality setting game, only the linear cost function Cj(Vj) = av; is relevant. Firms will never choose qualities beyond the domain of the linear function. When firm 1 chooses Vi > v, it bears a marginal cost Ci > vP If firm 1 can make a non-negative profit, i.e. pt £ c2, one has px > vP It implies 0vj - pt < 0 for all 0. So firm 1 can not sell any product. Similarly, if firm 2 chooses v2 > v°, then C2 > v2. We have p2 > v2 and 0v2 - p2 < 0. Firm 2 can sell nothing. Thus firm 1 would never choose a quality higher than v and firm 2 would never choose a quality higher than v°. To ensure an interior solution, assume that v° is sufficiently high so that in equilibrium it is not a binding constraint for firm 2.

If early announcement is committed, both firms know v while choosing qualities.

Under a late announcement policy, though, the quality setting game is played with asymmetric information. However, under either early or late announcement, qualities are commonly known when firms set prices.

3. Quality-Price Equilibrium

Let us start with the last stage price game. A consumer 0 prefers firm 1's product to firm 2’s if and only if 0v2 - pi > 0v2 - p2, i.e. 0 > 0 ' s : ^2. He gets a positive

V1 - V2

surplus from firm 2's product if and only if 0v2 - p2 > 0, or 0 > 0" = P2 If firm 2 can sell any product, there must exist some 0 > 0 such that 0v2 > p2 and 0v2 - p2 > 0vx - pP These two inequalities imply 0' > 0". Hence consumers with 0 s 0 ' purchase from firm 1, consumers with 0 G[0",0') purchase from firm 2 and those with 0 < 0" buy nothing. Thus the demand functions for firm 1 and firm 2 are

Xj = 1 PL--E2

Vi - v2 X2 =

Pl p2 _ £2 Vi - v2 " v2

Substituting the demand and marginal costs q = avf into profit functions xi(pi-ci), we get Jt! = (1 - P* ~ y2)(pi - avj) and - ^ )(p 2 - av2). One can solve the Nash equilibrium prices as

(1)

(8)

(2) These price strategies imply the following equilibrium profits

(3) The high quality firm makes a higher profit (not include the cost of innovation).

Both firms' profits are decreasing in a. One can check that — > 0 and > 0. Both profits rise with firm 1's quality. It is expected since a higher vx raises demand and

Firm 1's profit decreases with v2 given vx because less product differentiation leads to more intensive competition.

Then we consider the subgame perfect equilibrium for the quality setting game.

Firms choose qualities to maximize the profits in (3). As > 0, firm 1's optimal quality yields a corner solution. It always chooses the highest possible quality, v, regardless of early or late announcement. The low quality firm's quality decisions,

announcement policy, firm 2 knows v and hence knows vx. The equilibrium quality strategies are Vj = v and v2 = — . Since v is uncertain, so is firm 2's quality, v2.4v

Under a late announcement policy, firm 2 does not know v and has to choose a fixed v2 based on the distribution of v. The following first order condition gives the optimal value of v2:

(4)

(9)

6

Now v2 does not depend on the realization of v. We can show that n*2 is lower than the expected value of v2 under early announcement, ^E(v). Hence we get4

Proposition 1: While firm 1 always chooses the highest possible quality, its early announcement policy encourages firm 2 to choose a higher quality on average.

Prnnf. p r—~ * _ 1 2(4v_-7v,t )(4v-v^^

Proof. E{ 7 - v2) - y { v (4 v2 }•

v-v2):

Since ' > y y v 2 if and only if 4v > 7v2, E{v2^ _ v'*)3 v2E { ^ y y ^ r } = 0. Hence E ( y ) - v2 > 0.

(4v-v2)3 3456 4v-7v2 (4v-v2)3 3456

,2 r > 49 II On average late announcement yields more product differentiation and less competition. Firm 2 behaves like a risk averse firm: when facing uncertainty it becomes less aggressive on average.

We can also compare firms' demand under early and late announcement policies.

Substituting firms' price strategies (2) into the demand functions (1), one gets firms' demand functions as follows:

_ 2(1-0)21

1 4vi - v2 x2 (i-q)vi

4vx - v2* (5)

Firm 1's demand is always twice as large as firm 2's. Under an early announcement

4v 7 (l-a) 7(l-a)

policy, v2 = v and v2 = y the sales are constant with xx = anc* x2 = 24 '

_ 7(l-a) „

They are independent of the value of v. The market coverage is g . The rest of l+7a

8 consumers never purchase any product. As time goes by, the market coverage remains constant even though v keeps increasing.

2(l-a)v , (l-a)v _ Under a late announcement policy, the sales are Xi = 4v_y* and x2 = 4y_y* • The market share ratio remains 2 to 1, but the market coverage is no longer constant. It increases in the realization of v, given v2. The expected market coverage is 3(1-

(10)

v 7 v a)E(^~^*). Early announcement gives firms higher expected sales if > EQy y»).

Since this is indeed the case, we get

Proposition 2-. Early announcement increases both firms' expected sales, Proof: EG v x _ J _ ü r ; 4v-7v* (4v-V2)2

0 - 24E^V f4v-v;y v2 } 4v-V27 24i"1 ’ (4v-V2)3

(4v-v*)2 576 , , . „ * n 4v-7v* (4v-v*)2 576 Since if and only if 4v > 7v2, E{v2(4 v y ^ 3' } > —

('4v-7v?')v2 7 v

E{ Hence - E W > °-

Proposition 1 and Proposition 2 show that firm 2's expected quality and both firms' expected sales are distorted by early or late announcement. On the contrary, information sharing before quantity or price competition, for instance Vives (1984), does not affect the expected quantity, price or demand. It changes expected profits and consumer surplus only through the variance and covariance of quantities or prices. This is because the demand in the previous models is linear in quantities or prices and the equilibrium quantities and prices are linear in uncertain demand or costs. Here in our quality setting game, however, the demand is no longer linear in qualities and the equilibrium qualities are no longer linear in the random variable v.

4. Impact on Profits

The next question is how announcement policies affect profits. Substituting the equilibrium quality strategies under early announcement into profit functions (3), we obtain the equilibrium profits

7 1

= 48<1 -a )2y = ^ ( 1 -a)2v (6)

Both firms' profits linearly increase with v. The expected total profit is ^ (l-a )2E(v).1 Under a late announcement policy, the profits are

Jii = 4(1-a)2(vw ^v

(4v-vz) jr2 = (1-a)2(v-v2)YY2, (4v-V2)2

2 2 (7)

(11)

8

„ (4v+v*)(v-v*) „

The expected total profit is (l-a )2E{w— }• The difference between two

„ v v(4v+v*)(v-v*),

expected total profits is (l-a )2E{^ - (4 v v We s^ow t^iat negative. So the total profit is lower under an early announcement policy. Since an early announcement policy provides the low quality firm better information with no effect on the high quality firm's decision, it must benefit firm 2. Hence firm l's profit must fall more than firm 2's profit rises. Therefore we get

Proposition 3: An early announcement policy hurts the high quality firm more than it benefits the low quality firm.

„ „ ,v v(4v+v*)(v-v*), 1 r „ , 4v-7v2 Proof: - (4v-v*)2 } = ’

6E<

v

(8

v

2+2

v

V2-V2 )(4

v

-

v

^

4v-7v? * 94 * *

(4) implies E{2v2v2^ ~ T y } = 0. As 8v2 - v22 > "yvv2 if and only if 4v > 7v2,

> ^ E { v ^ > = 0. Hence < 0. ||

Intuitively an early announcement raises firm 2's quality on average. It reduces product differentiation and intensifies price competition. This result suggests that the high quality firm has no incentive to adapt an early announcement policy, even if a side payment is allowed. Thus a late announcement policy will be chosen.

5. Welfare Effect

We now examine the welfare effect of announcement policies. The total consumer surplus is the sum of the surplus of consumers who purchase either the high quality product or the low quality product. Adding this to the total profit one gets the social welfare. It can be written as

1 e'

SW = j Vl(0 - a)d0 + J v 2(0 - a)d0

e' 0"

= Vl{O.5(l-0'2) - a(l-0')} + v2{O.5(0'2-0"2) - a(0'-0")}

= VjX^l-a-O.SXi) + v2x2(l-a-X!-0.5x2) (8)

(12)

Substituting the equilibrium demand given by (5) into (8), one gets the social welfare 1 2v1(12v12-v1v2-2v22)

. Under late announcement its as a function of qualities, ^(l-« )2 v )2

1 „ 12v2-w*-2v*2

expected value is 2 (l-a)2E{v— (4V v*)2 ’ ^nder early announcement the expected social welfare is y ( l - a ) 2E(v). We now prove that the latter is bigger.11

11 12v2-W9-2v22 1 * * 4v i-7v2 Proof: E { y v - v (4v_y2*)2 '2 } = yE{v(32v2-28w 2*+5v2*2) ^ ^ }

(4) implies 28v2E{v2^ ^ ' v*p} = 0. Further, 32v2 + 5v*2 > y w 2 if and only if 4v - 7v2 > 0. Hence E{v(32v2+5v*2) ^ ^ } > ^ v*E{v2^ y ^ } = ' 0.

11 12v2-w ,-2v72

Therefore E { y v - v > 0. jj

We already know that the total profit is lower under early announcement. Therefore consumers must be better off more than the firms are worse off. In addition, early announcement reduces uncertainty faced by consumers and may also lower firms' marketing expenditures. All of these suggest

Proposition 4’. An early announcement policy is socially desirable.

The main reason is also due to less product differentiation. It induces more intensive competition and brings prices down. Lower prices not only give consumers more surplus, but also increase the number of consumers who purchase products. Since an early announcement policy is socially desirable, but not self-enforcing, there might be a need for government intervention to implement mandatory early announcement in such a vertically differentiated industry.

6. Concluding Remark

In the model we assumed that the innovative firm commits to either an early announcement or late announcement policy. As a matter of fact, one can alternatively let the firm announce any value of v subject to a continuous cost of misreporting. This would give a separating equilibrium. The low quality firm can

(13)

10

always infer the true value of v. The outcome is then essentially the same as the case of early announcement. If the cost of misreporting does not exist, the innovative firm, preferring v2 as low as possible, will always claim the lowest value of v, which is v°. This will result in a pooling equilibrium. The low quality firm can only make its quality decision based on the distribution of v. It corresponds to the case of late announcement. Hence the cases of early and late announcements can represent the situations where the innovative firm's cost of misreporting is significant or negligible. As we mentioned earlier, a cost of misreporting may come from the stock market or consumers reaction. Future research may include the stock market or consumers explicitly as reacting to the announcement. It may provide some justification about a cost of misreporting and explain how it works.

Another assumption in this paper is that only one firm innovates products. There are many cases, for example in the computer industry, where more than one firms conduct R&D and innovation announcements are used strategically for pre-emption.

It has different, though relevant aspects from this paper and may be better studied in a horizontal rather than vertical differentiation model. We are trying here to focus our attention on competition from a technical follower. Nevertheless the topic of innovation announcement with more than one innovators is quite interesting and worthwhile to pursue later.

(14)

REFERENCES:

Chaney, P., T. Devinney and R. Winer, 1991, The Impact of New Product Introductions on the Market Value of Firms, Journal of Business 64: 573-610

Eliashberg, J. and T. Robertson, 1988, New Product Preannouncing Behaviour: A Market Signalling Study, Journal of Marketing Research 25:282-292

Gal-Or, E., 1985, Information Sharing in Oligopoly, Econometrica, 53:329-343

Gal-Or, E., 1986, Information T ransm ission--- Cournot and Bertrand Equilibria, Review of Economic Studies, 53: 85-92

Gabszewicz, J. and F. Thisse, 1979, Price Competition, Quality and Income Disparities, Journal of Economic Theory 20: 340-359

Li, L., 1985, Cournot Oligopoly with Information Sharing, Rand Journal of Economics 16: 521-536 Novshek, W. and H. Sonnenschein, 1982, Fulfilled Expectations Cournot Duopoly with Information Acquisition and Release, Bell Journal of Economics 13:214-218

Sakai, Y., 1985, The Value o f Information in a Simple Duopoly Model, Journal of Economic Theory 36: 36-54

Shaked A. and J. Sutton, 1982, Relaxing Price Competition through Product Differentiation, Review of Economic Studies, 49: 3-13

Tirole, J., 1989, The Theory o f Industrial Organization, The MIT Press

Vives, X., 1984, Duopoly Information Equilibrium: Cournot and Bertrand, Journal of Economic Theory 34, 71-94

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

A very low tax will not prevent individuals who expect to gain a premium from investing in education that strictly exceeds their education cost, and the higher the tax on the

Lutz Engelhardt Entrepreneurial Business Models in the German Software Industry: Companies, Venture Capital, and Stock Market Based Growth Strategies of the.

Es wurde im Laufe der letzten Kapitel gezeigt, dass, legt man die idealtypische Unterscheidung zwischen einem 'konventionellen' deutschen Unter- nehmen und einem

For this purpose, we estimate expenditure functions of local governments of different size and determine cost elasticities with respect to municipalities’ demographic

Given the inherent unpopularity of tax increases (Niskanen, 1979; Vermeir and Heyndels, 2006), local politicians may see this as a viable – and electorally more rewarding (or,

In the second (final) period, subgame equilibria are consistent with a modified battleground-states strategy in which swing states are hotly contested, but parties stochas-

By lemma 2, total expected first round effort in an equilibrium with sep- aration in round one equals (1 − λ) 2 v/2, as in a symmetric one-shot contest with two-sided

We proceed as follows. In section 2 we describe the set of players, their sets of actions, the timing of moves, and their payoffs. In section 3 we solve for the equilibrium in